Preemption

Top charts of 2017: 12 charts that show the real problems policies must tackle, not the made-up ones

Download PDF

Inequalities, and the inequities in opportunity that they represent, permeate all areas of American society. The real problems policies must tackle include stagnating wages of American workers who have lost economic leverage, wage and wealth gaps based on race, and unequal educational opportunities for children from lower-income families. Unfortunately the policy focus of the last year, culminating in the end-of-year passage of massive tax cuts for corporations, addressed nonexistent problems rather than the real problems we face. EPI’s Top Charts of 2017 tell the story in images.

When workers have more leverage, income growth is more equal: Union membership and share of income going to the top 10 percent in the U.S., 1917–2015

1
Year Union membership Share of income going to the top 10 percent
1917 11.0% 40.3%
1918 12.1% 39.9%
1919 14.3% 39.5%
1920 17.5% 38.1%
1921 17.6% 42.9%
1922 14.0% 42.9%
1923 11.7% 40.6%
1924 11.3% 43.3%
1925 11.0% 44.2%
1926 10.7% 44.1%
1927 10.6% 44.7%
1928 10.4% 46.1%
1929 10.1% 43.8%
1930 10.7% 43.1%
1931 11.2% 44.4%
1932 11.3% 46.3%
1933 9.5% 45.0%
1934 9.8% 45.2%
1935 10.8% 43.4%
1936 11.1% 44.8%
1937 18.6% 43.3%
1938 23.9% 43.0%
1939 24.8% 44.6%
1940 23.5% 44.4%
1941 25.4% 41.0%
1942 24.2% 35.5%
1943 30.1% 32.7%
1944 32.5% 31.5%
1945 33.4% 32.6%
1946 31.9% 34.6%
1947 31.1% 33.0%
1948 30.5% 33.7%
1949 29.6% 33.8%
1950 30.0% 33.9%
1951 32.4% 32.8%
1952 31.5% 32.1%
1953 33.2% 31.4%
1954 32.7% 32.1%
1955 32.9% 31.8%
1956 33.2% 31.8%
1957 32.0% 31.7%
1958 31.1% 32.1%
1959 31.6% 32.0%
1960 30.7% 31.7%
1961 28.7% 31.9%
1962 29.1% 32.0%
1963 28.5% 32.0%
1964 28.5% 31.6%
1965 28.6% 31.5%
1966 28.7% 32.0%
1967 28.6% 32.0%
1968 28.7% 32.0%
1969 28.3% 31.8%
1970 27.9% 31.5%
1971 27.4% 31.8%
1972 27.5% 31.6%
1973 27.1% 31.9%
1974 26.5% 32.4%
1975 25.7% 32.6%
1976 25.7% 32.4%
1977 25.2% 32.4%
1978 24.7% 32.4%
1979 25.4% 32.3%
1980 23.6% 32.9%
1981 22.3% 32.7%
1982 21.6% 33.2%
1983 21.4% 33.7%
1984 20.5% 33.9%
1985 19.0% 34.3%
1986 18.5% 34.6%
1987 17.9% 36.5%
1988 17.6% 38.6%
1989 17.2% 38.5%
1990 16.7% 38.8%
1991 16.2% 38.4%
1992 16.2% 39.8%
1993 16.2% 39.5%
1994 16.1% 39.6%
1995 15.3% 40.5%
1996 14.9% 41.2%
1997 14.7% 41.7%
1998 14.2% 42.1%
1999 13.9% 42.7%
2000 13.5% 43.1%
2001 13.5% 42.2%
2002 13.3% 42.4%
2003 12.9% 42.8%
2004 12.5% 43.6%
2005 12.5% 44.9%
2006 12.0% 45.5%
2007 12.1% 45.7%
2008 12.4% 46.0%
2009 12.3% 45.5%
2010 11.9% 46.4%
2011 11.8% 46.6%
2012 11.2% 47.8%
2013 11.2% 46.7%
2014 11.1% 47.3%
2015 11.1% 47.8%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

The U.S. economy is more equitable when workers have the freedom to join together and bargain collectively through a union. The bottom line in the graph shows a sharp rise in union membership after enactment of the National Labor Relations Act (NLRA) in 1935. (The NLRA itself was the outcome of an explosion of worker organizing around 1920). For decades the NLRA protected workers’ rights to negotiate with their employers—rights that workers used to secure a fairer share of overall income generated in the economy. This worker leverage led to decades of fast and equitable economic growth that persisted through the 1970s. The top line in the graph shows that the top 10 percent of Americans collected almost half of all income in the late 1920s and early 1930s, but only around a third by the 1950s, when union membership was at its peak and gains were spread more evenly to the bottom 90 percent.

In the 1970s fierce corporate opposition to unions, coupled with policymakers’ failure to protect private-sector workers’ collective bargaining rights, led to policies and practices that strangled union organizing in the private sector. The rapid de-unionization that ensued contributed to wage declines for all workers and reversed much of the economic progress that had been made by the broad American middle class in the decades following World War II. While the NLRA still protects workers’ rights to unionize, the law has not kept up with the onslaught of employer anti-union practices. The graph shows that as union membership declined, the top 10 percent’s share of all income rose, returning to Great Depression levels by the 2010s.

Janus v. AFSCME, a case that will be argued before the U.S. Supreme Court in February 2017, could accelerate growing inequality. A decision in favor of the plaintiff in Janus would outlaw mandatory fair share fees in the public sector—letting nonunion members in a school or fire department or other public workplace benefit from union representation but not pay for it. This opens the door for employers to use fear and intimidation to erode financial support for—and thus membership in—public-sector unions the same way that anti-union legislation (such as so-called “right-to-work” laws) has eroded union membership in the private sector.

Share this chart:

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Working people saving for retirement are losing billions: The administration has delayed a rule protecting retirement savers against financial advisers with conflicts of interest

2
Working people saving for retirement are losing billions: The administration has delayed a rule protecting retirement savers against financial advisers with conflicts of interest

Source: Adapted from Heidi Shierholz and Ben Zipperer, Here Is What’s at Stake with the Conflict of Interest (‘Fiduciary’) Rule, Economic Policy Institute fact sheet, May 30, 2017.

The fiduciary rule is an Obama-era regulation that protects Americans’ hard-earned retirement savings by requiring that financial professionals offering retirement investment advice put their clients’ interests first. The rule was supposed to be implemented on April 10, 2017. But the Trump administration has repeatedly delayed enforcement of the rule, most recently to July 1, 2019, and is using the rule-making process and delays to significantly weaken the rule.

Because of the enforcement delays, industry actors presenting themselves as neutral advisers can continue to steer retirement savers to products with high fees and commissions that benefit the advisers but reduce net returns for the client. The map shows the annual costs retirement savers in each state incur due to underperforming IRA assets that are invested in products for which savers received “conflicted” advice (that is, advice provided by financial advisers whose earnings depend on the actions taken by the client).1

EPI has used the data on annual losses to retirement savers from conflicted advice to estimate that an August 2017 Department of Labor directive delaying the rule for 18 months, to July 1, 2019, would cost workers saving for retirement $10.9 billion dollars over the next 30 years.

1. Underperformance of investment returns in which savers received conflicted advice can be attributed to a wide range of factors, including high fees, high trading costs, poor market timing, and increased risk exposure without increased returns.

Share this chart:

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

The U.S. economy can afford a $15 minimum wage: The value of the federal minimum wage in 2017 if it had kept up with a growing economy

3
Actual minimum wage (2017$) If it had grown with average wages of typical workers If it had grown with productivity
1938  $       3.80
1939  $       4.63
1940  $       4.60
1941  $       4.38
1942  $       3.95
1943  $       3.72
1944  $       3.66
1945  $       4.77
1946  $       4.40
1947  $       3.85
1948  $       3.56 $5.67
1949  $       3.61 $5.75
1950  $       6.68 $5.84
1951  $       6.19 $6.29
1952  $       6.07 $6.46
1953  $       6.03 $6.65
1954  $       5.98 $6.88
1955  $       6.00 $6.99
1956  $       7.89 $7.28
1957  $       7.63 $7.29
1958  $       7.42 $7.49
1959  $       7.37 $7.64
1960  $       7.25 $7.92
1961  $       8.25 $8.06
1962  $       8.17 $8.31
1963  $       8.76 $8.62
1964  $       8.65 $8.92
1965  $       8.51 $9.21
1966  $       8.28 $9.49
1967  $       8.99 $9.78
1968  $       9.90    $                    9.90 $9.90
1969  $       9.47  $                 10.08 $9.94
1970  $       9.03  $                 10.18 $10.08
1971  $       8.66  $                 10.39 $10.46
1972  $       8.40  $                 10.85 $10.73
1973  $       7.90  $                 10.83 $10.99
1974  $       8.99  $                 10.56 $10.82
1975  $       8.71  $                 10.41 $11.06
1976  $       9.03  $                 10.54 $11.37
1977  $       8.49  $                 10.64 $11.50
1978  $       9.15  $                 10.76 $11.59
1979  $       9.15  $                 10.60 $11.61
1980  $       8.80  $                 10.30 $11.52
1981  $       8.68  $                 10.22 $11.77
1982  $       8.19  $                 10.19 $11.59
1983  $       7.85  $                 10.19 $11.94
1984  $       7.54  $                 10.13 $12.25
1985  $       7.29  $                 10.08 $12.46
1986  $       7.16  $                 10.11 $12.72
1987  $       6.93  $                 10.02 $12.78
1988  $       6.68  $                    9.98 $12.93
1989  $       6.41  $                    9.93 $13.03
1990  $       6.92  $                    9.85 $13.22
1991  $       7.47  $                    9.80 $13.30
1992  $       7.29  $                    9.79 $13.80
1993  $       7.11  $                    9.80 $13.85
1994  $       6.97  $                    9.85 $13.96
1995  $       6.80  $                    9.88 $14.02
1996  $       7.40  $                    9.95 $14.29
1997  $       7.86  $                 10.11 $14.53
1998  $       7.75  $                 10.38 $14.83
1999  $       7.59  $                 10.53 $15.22
2000  $       7.34  $                 10.59 $15.55
2001  $       7.14  $                 10.68 $15.79
2002  $       7.03  $                 10.82 $16.24
2003  $       6.87  $                 10.87 $16.77
2004  $       6.69  $                 10.80 $17.22
2005  $       6.47  $                 10.74 $17.52
2006  $       6.27  $                 10.80 $17.62
2007  $       6.92  $                 10.92 $17.74
2008  $       7.47  $                 10.92 $17.78
2009  $       8.29  $                 11.29 $18.15
2010  $       8.16  $                 11.37 $18.68
2011  $       7.91  $                 11.24 $18.71
2012  $       7.75  $                 11.18 $18.81
2013  $       7.64  $                 11.24 $18.87
2014  $       7.52  $                 11.32 $18.97
2015  $       7.51  $                 11.54 $19.07
2016  $       7.41  $                 11.68 $19.10
2017  $       7.25   $                 11.62 $19.33 
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Growth in average wages of typical workers measures average wages of production/nonsupervisory workers. Inflation is measured using the CPI-U-RS and the CPI projection for 2017 from the Congressional Budget Office. Productivity is measured as total economy productivity net depreciation.

Source: Adapted from David Cooper, Another Year of Congressional Inaction Has Further Eroded the Federal Minimum Wage, Economic Policy Institute Economic Snapshot, July 24, 2017.

The federal minimum wage was established in 1938 to help ensure that regular employment provided a decent quality of life. By making periodic increases in the minimum wage, Congress also guaranteed that the country’s lowest-paid workers would share in the benefits of broader improvements in the economy. For the first 30 years of the minimum wage’s existence, regular raises allowed the minimum wage to keep pace with growth in economy-wide productivity. But, as the graph shows, since the 1970s Congress has failed to adjust the minimum wage to match the economy’s capacity for higher wages—leaving low-wage workers behind.

The bottom line shows how inflation has eroded the buying power of a minimum wage income even as the economy grew and was able to afford a higher minimum wage. If you were paid the $7.25 minimum wage in 2017, you made 27 percent less—in inflation-adjusted terms—than someone who earned the minimum wage in 1968 (when the value of the federal minimum wage peaked, at $9.90 in 2017 dollars). The middle line shows that if the minimum wage had kept up with average wage growth for typical U.S. workers (specifically, production and nonsupervisory workers, who constitute essentially the bottom 80 percent of the workforce) since 1968, it would be $11.62 an hour. But even that would not have been sufficient to distribute the fruits of economic growth equitably. If the minimum wage had kept pace with rising productivity since 1968, someone earning the minimum wage in 2017 would have received $19.33 an hour—and millions of people earning above the minimum wage today would also be getting higher wages than they currently do.

The expectation that the minimum wage rise in step with broader trends in the economy would not have been unreasonable for previous generations—that was the trend throughout the 1950s and 1960s. Today’s minimum wage workers have been harmed both by the failure to raise the minimum wage in step with pay for typical workers and by the huge and growing gap between these nonsupervisory wages and economy-wide productivity. The Raise the Wage Act of 2017 would raise the federal minimum wage to $15 by 2024. Such a raise would certainly bring the pay of minimum wage workers closer to providing a decent quality of life, even though it would still fall short of what the economy could have delivered for low-wage workers over the past 50 years.

Share this chart:

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

The U.S. economy is not suffering from 'too high' corporate taxes: After-tax corporate profits versus corporate tax revenue, as a share of GDP, 1952–2015

4
Fiscal year Corporate income tax revenue After-tax corporate profits
1952 5.9% 5.5%
1953 5.6% 5.1%
1954 5.4% 5.6%
1955 4.4% 6.6%
1956 4.8% 6.2%
1957 4.6% 5.8%
1958 4.2% 5.2%
1959 3.4% 6.1%
1960 4.0% 5.9%
1961 3.8% 5.9%
1962 3.5% 6.6%
1963 3.5% 6.9%
1964 3.5% 7.2%
1965 3.6% 7.8%
1966 3.8% 7.6%
1967 4.1% 7.1%
1968 3.2% 6.6%
1969 3.7% 5.7%
1970 3.1% 4.8%
1971 2.4% 5.4%
1972 2.6% 5.8%
1973 2.7% 5.8%
1974 2.6% 4.7%
1975 2.5% 5.2%
1976 2.3% 5.8%
1977 2.7% 6.3%
1978 2.6% 6.5%
1979 2.6% 6.0%
1980 2.3% 4.8%
1981 1.9% 5.1%
1982 1.5%  4.9%
1983 1.0% 5.5%
1984 1.4% 5.9%
1985 1.4% 5.9%
1986 1.4% 4.7%
1987 1.8% 4.8%
1988 1.8% 5.2%
1989 1.9% 4.7%
1990 1.6% 4.5%
1991 1.6% 5.1%
1992 1.6% 5.0%
1993 1.7% 5.1%
1994 2.0% 5.9%
1995 2.1% 6.3%
1996 2.2% 6.8%
1997 2.1% 7.2%
1998 2.1% 6.1%
1999 1.9% 5.9%
2000 2.0% 5.0%
2001 1.4% 5.2%
2002 1.4% 6.5%
2003 1.2% 7.1%
2004 1.6% 8.0%
2005 2.2% 8.1%
2006 2.6% 8.5%
2007 2.6% 7.5%
2008 2.1% 6.6%
2009 1.0% 7.8%
2010 1.3% 9.2%
2011 1.2% 9.3%
2012 1.5% 9.6%
2013 1.6% 9.4%
2014 1.9% 9.3%
2015 1.9% 8.5%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Source: Adapted from Josh Bivens and Hunter Blair, ‘Competitive’ Distractions: Cutting Corporate Tax Rates Will Not Create Jobs or Boost Incomes for the Vast Majority of American Families, Economic Policy Institute, May 9, 2017.

In the recent tax debate, proponents of corporate tax cuts once again trotted out the myth that taxes on American corporations are excessive and are responsible for recent slow economic growth. These proponents claim that cutting corporate tax rates will encourage companies to make productivity-boosting investments that would increase wages. We’ve noted the many ways this claim fails when tested against real-world evidence.

But the simplest rebuttal to this claim is this graph, which shows that corporate taxes as a share of the U.S. economy have been extraordinarily low in recent years, even as corporate profits have been historically high. At a time when ginned-up hysteria over federal budget deficits is used to attack crucial social insurance and income support programs like Social Security, Medicare, and nutrition assistance, it is odd that we’d ask even less of corporations when it comes to collecting taxes.

Share this chart:

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Cuts to social programs would push millions of Americans into poverty: 44,566,000 people were in poverty in 2016—below are the additional number of people that would have been in poverty without the specified government program

5
Additional number of people in poverty
Social Security 26,096,000 0
Refundable tax credits 8,177,000 0
SNAP/Food stamps 3,575,000 0
SSI 3,359,000 0
Housing subsidies 3,106,000 0
School lunch 1,361,000 0
TANF/general assistance 608,000 0
Unemployment insurance 680,000 0
Workers’ compensation 242,000 0
WIC 264,000 0
LIHEAP 150,000 0
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Notes: Poverty in this chart is measured by the Supplemental Poverty Measure (SPM). SNAP refers to the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program. The Supplemental Security Income (SSI) program pays benefits to adults and children with a disability and who have limited income and resources, and people age 65 or older who have limited income and resources. TANF refers to Temporary Assistance for Needy Families. WIC refers to the Special Supplemental Nutrition Program for Woman, Infants, and Children. LIHEAP refers to the Low Income Home Energy Assistance Program.

Source: David Cooper and Julia Wolfe, “Poverty Declined Modestly in 2016; Government Programs Continued to Keep Tens of Millions Out of Poverty,” Working Economics (Economic Policy Institute blog), September 12, 2017.

While taxes dominated the end-of-year agenda, cuts to the social safety net are looming. Republicans in Congress passed a budget resolution in October calling for draconian cuts to Medicare, Medicaid, and a number of key safety net programs like food stamps and Supplemental Security Income (SSI). In the wake of tax cuts providing huge benefits to the richest households and corporations, Republicans in Congress will likely assert that the federal budget deficit demands that we make these spending cuts. This predictable response would represent a triumph of chutzpah over economics. As past EPI research has shown, the deficit is not a pressing economic problem. But “deficit hysteria”—ginned up over decades by policymakers and analysts in both parties—could provide political cover for making cuts to popular social programs that would otherwise be politically impossible. This will devastate families that rely on these programs.

As the chart shows, these programs keep tens of millions of people out of poverty. For example, eliminating food stamps would push 3.6 million people, including 1.5 million children, into poverty, as measured by the Supplemental Poverty Measure. This cut alone would raise the total number of people in poverty to more than 48 million. Eliminating Supplemental Security Income would push 3.4 million people into poverty, including adults and children with disabilities. Eliminating housing subsidies would push 3.1 million people into poverty. (For more in the age breakdown of the population affected by these programs, see EPI’s expanded chart from September 2017, “Without government programs, millions more would be in poverty.”)

Share this chart:

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

The racial wealth gap is the clearest legacy of past discrimination in housing markets: Average and median household wealth in the United States, by race

6
White Black
Average $933,700 $138,200
Median $171,000 $17,600

 

ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Source: Adapted from Janelle Jones, “The Racial Wealth Gap: How African Americans Have Been Shortchanged out of the Materials to Build Wealth,” Working Economics (Economic Policy Institute blog), February 13, 2017.

The legacy of economic disadvantage for black Americans is apparent in the enormous wealth divide between black and white families in the United States. In 2016 the average white household had nearly seven times as much wealth ($933,700 in financial assets minus liabilities) as the average black household (which had a net worth of $138,200). This relative disparity grows when looking at “typical,” or median, households (those in the exact middle). In 2016, the net worth of the typical white household was $171,000, almost ten times the $17,600 in wealth held by the typical black household. What the chart does not show is that these gaps persist even after accounting for age, household structure, education level, income, and occupation.

These numbers are as disturbing for the past inequities they represent as for the future opportunity gaps they foretell. Wealth provides a buffer of economic security against periods of unemployment, enables families to finance a child’s college education or a new business venture, and helps finance a comfortable retirement. But African Americans have been shortchanged out of the materials to build wealth. Besides facing discrimination in employment and wages, black families historically have been shut out of the most important wealth-building market: housing. Overall, home equity makes up about two-thirds of all wealth for the typical household. In short, for median families, the racial wealth gap is overwhelmingly a housing wealth gap. And this housing wealth gap is no accident; it is the outcome of intentional policies at all levels of government, in particular housing policies that prevented blacks from acquiring land, created redlining and restrictive covenants, and encouraged lending discrimination. These policies created and reinforced the racial wealth gap we are still struggling to address.

Share this chart:

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Gender and racial pay gaps are not simply a function of voluntary occupational choice: Average hourly wages of black women and white men by occupation

7
Occupation  Black women  White men
Accountants/auditors $27.51 $39.23
Customer service reps 15.07 19.89
Teachers 25.65 30.50
Financial managers 27.61 47.93
Lawyers 43.00 54.94
Physicians/surgeons 36.94 54.94
Registered nurses 26.40 31.64
Retail salespersons 10.99 20.12
Social workers 22.81 27.09
Software developers 32.84 46.33
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Hourly wages shown are 2012 to 2016 averages from the Current Population Survey. Teacher category includes elementary and middle school teachers.

Source: Adapted from Figure B in Valerie Wilson, Janelle Jones, Kayla Blado, and Elise Gould, “Black Women Have to Work 7 Months into 2017 to Be Paid the Same as White Men in 2016,” Working Economics (Economic Policy Institute blog), July 28, 2017.

On average, black women workers are paid only 67 cents on the dollar relative to white non-Hispanic men, after controlling for education, years of experience, and location (using 2016 data). This distressing statistic reflects the dual inequities faced by black women—they are subject to both a racial pay gap and a gender pay gap. A key focus of those committed to a fairer economy should be closing these gaps and accelerating economic progress for black women. A number of myths block steps toward real solutions, including the myth that racial and gender pay gaps are simply due to black women making unconstrained choices to pursue careers that pay less. In reality, occupational segregation is not simply a voluntary choice, but is clearly affected by discrimination both before and after people begin their careers. Further, racial and gender pay gaps persist even within occupations.

The chart shows the average wages of black women and white men in a range of occupations. In every occupation shown—both female-dominated and male-dominated—black women earn less than white men. White male physicians and surgeons earn, on average, $18.00 per hour more than black women doing the same job ($54.94 versus $36.94). The gap for retail salespersons is also shocking, at more than $9.00 an hour ($20.12 versus $10.99). The data confirm that black women are underpaid, period.

Share this chart:

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Steady increase in the share of prime-age adults with jobs was underway before the current administration took office: Share of adults age 25 to 54 with jobs, 2000–2017

8
Date Actual Autopilot projection 2000 annual average
Jan-2000 81.8 81.46
Feb-2000 81.8 81.46
Mar-2000 81.7 81.46
Apr-2000 81.9 81.46
May-2000 81.5 81.46
Jun-2000 81.5 81.46
Jul-2000 81.3 81.46
Aug-2000 81.1 81.46
Sep-2000 81.1 81.46
Oct-2000 81.1 81.46
Nov-2000 81.3 81.46
Dec-2000 81.4 81.46
Jan-2001 81.4 81.46
Feb-2001 81.3 81.46
Mar-2001 81.3 81.46
Apr-2001 80.9 81.46
May-2001 80.8 81.46
Jun-2001 80.6 81.46
Jul-2001 80.5 81.46
Aug-2001 80.2 81.46
Sep-2001 80.2 81.46
Oct-2001 79.9 81.46
Nov-2001 79.7 81.46
Dec-2001 79.8 81.46
Jan-2002 79.6 81.46
Feb-2002 79.8 81.46
Mar-2002 79.6 81.46
Apr-2002 79.5 81.46
May-2002 79.4 81.46
Jun-2002 79.2 81.46
Jul-2002 79.1 81.46
Aug-2002 79.3 81.46
Sep-2002 79.4 81.46
Oct-2002 79.2 81.46
Nov-2002 78.8 81.46
Dec-2002 79 81.46
Jan-2003 78.9 81.46
Feb-2003 78.9 81.46
Mar-2003 79 81.46
Apr-2003 79.1 81.46
May-2003 78.9 81.46
Jun-2003 78.9 81.46
Jul-2003 78.8 81.46
Aug-2003 78.7 81.46
Sep-2003 78.6 81.46
Oct-2003 78.6 81.46
Nov-2003 78.7 81.46
Dec-2003 78.8 81.46
Jan-2004 78.9 81.46
Feb-2004 78.8 81.46
Mar-2004 78.7 81.46
Apr-2004 78.9 81.46
May-2004 79 81.46
Jun-2004 79.1 81.46
Jul-2004 79.2 81.46
Aug-2004 79 81.46
Sep-2004 79 81.46
Oct-2004 79 81.46
Nov-2004 79.1 81.46
Dec-2004 78.9 81.46
Jan-2005 79.2 81.46
Feb-2005 79.2 81.46
Mar-2005 79.2 81.46
Apr-2005 79.4 81.46
May-2005 79.5 81.46
Jun-2005 79.2 81.46
Jul-2005 79.4 81.46
Aug-2005 79.6 81.46
Sep-2005 79.4 81.46
Oct-2005 79.3 81.46
Nov-2005 79.2 81.46
Dec-2005 79.3 81.46
Jan-2006 79.6 81.46
Feb-2006 79.7 81.46
Mar-2006 79.8 81.46
Apr-2006 79.6 81.46
May-2006 79.7 81.46
Jun-2006 79.8 81.46
Jul-2006 79.8 81.46
Aug-2006 79.8 81.46
Sep-2006 79.9 81.46
Oct-2006 80.1 81.46
Nov-2006 80 81.46
Dec-2006 80.1 81.46
Jan-2007 80.3 81.46 
Feb-2007 80.1 81.46
Mar-2007 80.2 81.46
Apr-2007 80 81.46
May-2007 80 81.46
Jun-2007 79.9 81.46
Jul-2007 79.8 81.46
Aug-2007 79.8 81.46
Sep-2007 79.7 81.46
Oct-2007 79.6 81.46
Nov-2007 79.7 81.46
Dec-2007 79.7 81.46
Jan-2008 80 81.46
Feb-2008 79.9 81.46
Mar-2008 79.8 81.46
Apr-2008 79.6 81.46
May-2008 79.5 81.46
Jun-2008 79.4 81.46
Jul-2008 79.2 81.46
Aug-2008 78.8 81.46
Sep-2008 78.8 81.46
Oct-2008 78.4 81.46
Nov-2008 78.1 81.46
Dec-2008 77.6 81.46
Jan-2009 77 81.46
Feb-2009 76.7 81.46
Mar-2009 76.2 81.46
Apr-2009 76.2 81.46
May-2009 75.9 81.46
Jun-2009 75.9 81.46
Jul-2009 75.8 81.46
Aug-2009 75.6 81.46
Sep-2009 75.1 81.46
Oct-2009 75 81.46
Nov-2009 75.2 81.46
Dec-2009 74.8 81.46
Jan-2010 75.1 81.46
Feb-2010 75.1 81.46
Mar-2010 75.1 81.46
Apr-2010 75.4 81.46
May-2010 75.1 81.46
Jun-2010 75.2 81.46
Jul-2010 75.1 81.46
Aug-2010 75 81.46
Sep-2010 75.1 81.46
Oct-2010 75 81.46
Nov-2010 74.8 81.46
Dec-2010 75 81.46
Jan-2011 75.2 81.46
Feb-2011 75.1 81.46
Mar-2011 75.3 81.46
Apr-2011 75.1 81.46
May-2011 75.2 81.46
Jun-2011 75 81.46
Jul-2011 75 81.46
Aug-2011 75.1 81.46
Sep-2011 74.9 81.46
Oct-2011 74.9 81.46
Nov-2011 75.3 81.46
Dec-2011 75.4 81.46
Jan-2012 75.5 81.46
Feb-2012 75.5 81.46
Mar-2012 75.7 81.46
Apr-2012 75.7 81.46
May-2012 75.7 81.46
Jun-2012 75.6 81.46
Jul-2012 75.6 81.46
Aug-2012 75.7 81.46
Sep-2012 76 81.46
Oct-2012 76.1 81.46
Nov-2012 75.8 81.46
Dec-2012 76 81.46
Jan-2013 75.6 81.46
Feb-2013 75.8 81.46
Mar-2013 75.8 81.46
Apr-2013 75.9 81.46
May-2013 76 81.46
Jun-2013 75.9 81.46
Jul-2013 76 81.46
Aug-2013 75.9 81.46
Sep-2013 76 81.46
Oct-2013 75.6 81.46
Nov-2013 76.1 81.46
Dec-2013 76.2 81.46
Jan-2014 76.4 81.46
Feb-2014 76.4 81.46
Mar-2014 76.6 81.46
Apr-2014 76.5 81.46
May-2014 76.4 81.46
Jun-2014 76.8 81.46
Jul-2014 76.7 81.46
Aug-2014 76.8 81.46
Sep-2014 76.8 81.46
Oct-2014 77 81.46
Nov-2014 77 81.46
Dec-2014 77.1 81.46
Jan-2015 77.1 81.46
Feb-2015 77.2 81.46
Mar-2015 77.2 81.46
Apr-2015 77.2 81.46
May-2015 77.2 81.46
Jun-2015 77.2 81.46
Jul-2015 77.1 81.46
Aug-2015 77.2 81.46
Sep-2015 77.3 81.46
Oct-2015 77.3 81.46
Nov-2015 77.5 81.46
Dec-2015 77.5 81.46
Jan-2016 77.7 81.46
Feb-2016 77.8 81.46
Mar-2016 78 81.46
Apr-2016 77.7 81.46
May-2016 77.8 81.46
Jun-2016 77.8 81.46
Jul-2016 78 81.46
Aug-2016 77.8 81.46
Sep-2016 78 81.46
Oct-2016 78.2 81.46
Nov-2016 78.2 81.46
Dec-2016 78.2 81.46
Jan-2017 78.2  78.2 81.46
Feb-2017 78.3 78.2528 81.46
Mar-2017 78.5 78.3056 81.46
Apr-2017 78.6 78.3583 81.46
May-2017 78.4 78.4111 81.46
Jun-2017 78.5 78.4639 81.46
Jul-2017 78.7 78.5167 81.46
Aug-2017 78.4 78.5694 81.46
Sep-2017 78.9 78.6222 81.46
Oct-2017 78.8 78.675 81.46
Nov-2017 79  78.7278 81.46
Dec-2017 78.7806 81.46
Jan-2018 78.8333 81.46
Feb-2018 78.8861 81.46
Mar-2018 78.9389 81.46
Apr-2018 78.9917 81.46
May-2018 79.0444 81.46
Jun-2018 79.0972 81.46
Jul-2018 79.15 81.46
Aug-2018 79.2028 81.46
Sep-2018 79.2556 81.46
Oct-2018 79.3083 81.46
Nov-2018 79.3611 81.46
Dec-2018 79.4139 81.46
Jan-2019 79.4667 81.46
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Notes: Dotted line denotes President Trump's January 2017 inauguration.

Source: Adapted from Figure 2 in “Autopilot Economy Tracker: Benchmarks to Beat in Order to Claim Policy-Driven Improvements to American Wages and Employment,” Economic Policy Institute, last updated December 8, 2017.

In 2017, there was no meaningful pickup in the pace at which the labor market is improving. This figure shows the share of 25- to 54-year-olds (“prime-age adults,” in the jargon of economists) who are employed. From November 2013 to November 2016, this share rose by 2.1 percentage points, or an average of 0.7 percentage points per year. From November 2016 to November 2017, this share rose by 0.8 percentage points.

EPI set up the Autopilot economy tracker at the beginning of 2017 so that claims about changing economic indicators—such as the share of prime-age adults who are employed—could be judged in context. By pinpointing where key indicators were already heading, the tracker shows that the new administration inherited an economy that was already on the upswing. In fact, the economy has made steady and significant progress toward full economic health in every year since 2009. This progress continued in 2017, but not at a pace that was significantly greater than in recent years.

This failure of employment growth to measurably improve under the Trump administration is no surprise. So far, policymakers have enacted no measures that would measurably boost job growth (though plenty of policies have been passed to erode workers’ bargaining power and hurt their wage growth). Employment growth in 2017 simply represents the upswing that was already underway before 2017 began.

Finally, the on-trend improvement that we have seen in 2017 owes more to the Fed’s decisions to not raise interest rates aggressively enough to stomp out job growth than it does to anything the current administration has accomplished. Before too long the Trump administration (and the rest of us) may well regret its decision to not renew Janet Yellen’s term as Fed chair, as her successor may not follow her cautious approach to raising rates.

Share this chart:

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Monthly private-sector job growth was slower in 2017 than previous years: Average monthly private-sector job growth, 2006–2017

9
Year Average monthly private sector payroll growth
2006 156
2007 73
2008 -278
2009 -434
2010 106
2011 198
2012 179
2013 209
2014 239
2015 213
2016 172
2017 170
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Notes: Because full 2017 monthly employment data are not yet available, the chart compares average monthly job growth between January and November for each of these years.

Source: Data are from the Current Employment Statistics (CES) series of the Bureau of Labor Statistics and are subject to occasional revisions. This chart was based on data accessed in December 2017.

Average monthly private-sector job growth in the first 11 months of 2017 fell short of both prior years’ tallies and the Trump administration’s own job creation goals. With an average of 170,000 new jobs being added each month, private-sector job growth in the first 11 months of 2017 was slower than in any year since 2010. Some of this slowdown might be because the economy is moving closer to full employment. The huge stock of unemployed workers created by the Great Recession was largely reabsorbed into the economy in the years following 2009 and boosted job growth above its long-run trend between 2010 and 2016. But we shouldn’t be too quick to assume there’s no more slack in the labor market. For example, the share of prime-age workers with jobs remains quite depressed relative to previous job-market recoveries, as shown in the previous top chart. That suggests there still may be ample room to pull in workers who were idled by the economic crisis.

Early in its term, the Trump administration announced that it would create 25 million new jobs over a decade. Essentially, to meet this claim the economy would need to add an average of 208,000 jobs each month over the next 10 years. This monthly tally is ambitious but actually achievable for the first few of those years if the economy were to continue to absorb idled workers. But as the figure shows, even this moderately ambitious benchmark has been missed in 2017. And this monthly tally would be near impossible to meet toward the end of those 10 years, once most of the idled prime-age workers have been absorbed into the labor market. As EPI analysis has shown, adding 25 million new jobs in a decade would require massive immigration or forcing elderly Americans to work at unprecedented rates.

Share this chart:

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Median household income made historic gains from 2014 to 2016: Adjusted median income of working-age and all households, 1995–2016

10
All households- imputed series All households- new series Working-age households- imputed series Working age households- new series
1995 $55,020 $63,173
1996 $55,808 $64,338
1997 $56,956 $65,168
1998 $59,036 $67,820
1999 $60,506 $69,548
2000 $60,380 $69,890
2001 $59,062 $68,811
2002 $58,384  $68,120
2003 $58,313 $67,499
2004 $58,118 $66,717
2005 $58,752 $66,273
2006 $59,208 $67,184
2007 $59,993 $67,492
2008 $57,856 $65,280
2009 $57,454 $64,392
2010 $55,961 $62,738
2011 $55,106 $61,220
2012 $55,025 $61,823
2013 $55,209 $55,209 $62,092 $62,092
2014 $54,404 $61,304
2015 $57,231 $64,146
2016 $59,039  $66,487
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Because of a redesign in the Current Population Survey Annual Social and Economic Supplement (CPS ASEC) income questions in 2013, we imputed the historical series using the ratio of the old and new method in 2013. Solid lines are actual CPS ASEC data; dashed lines denote historical values imputed by applying the new methodology to past income trends. Working age households are those in which the head of household is younger than age 65. Shaded areas denote recessions.

Source: Adapted from Elise Gould and Julia Wolfe, “Income Growth in 2016 Is Strong, but Not as Strong as 2015 and More Uneven,” Working Economics (Economic Policy Institute blog), September 12, 2017.

The median income of working-age households grew faster in 2015 than in any previous year. Growth in 2016 was also among the strongest on record for this statistic. This two-year span of historically rapid growth raised the median income of working-age households to $66,487 in 2016, up from $61,304 in 2014.

This growth occurred before the Trump administration was in place. Data on what happened to median household income in the first year of the administration will be available in fall 2018.

The strong growth in household income in 2015 and 2016 does not make up for the brutal hit to household incomes inflicted by the Great Recession and the slow recovery that has followed. But this growth absolutely constituted a welcome new trend and offers hope that middle-class households might really, finally, gain something from the steady recovery.

Share this chart:

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Income-based skills gaps are present in kindergarten: Gaps in skills between high-SES and low-SES kindergartners in 2010

11
In 2010
Reading 1.17
Math 1.25
Self-control 0.39
Approaches to learning 0.51
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: SES refers to socioeconomic status.

Source: Adapted from Figure A in Emma Garcia and Elaine Weiss, Education Inequalities at the School Starting Gate: Gaps, Trends, and Strategies to Address Them, Economic Policy Institute and Broader Bolder Approach to Education, September 27, 2017.

The large and persistent gaps in educational attainment between children of different races and income levels in the United States are profoundly disturbing. If education is to truly serve as a vehicle for upward mobility, these gaps must be closed. We will make little headway toward this goal if we don’t address the many ways that inequality contributes to these gaps.

The chart presents stark evidence that the broader inequities extending all through the American economy contribute to these gaps: the presence of skills gaps before formal education even starts. As the chart shows, low socioeconomic status (SES) children begin kindergarten already well behind their high-SES peers.

Socioeconomic status is a composite of information on parents’ educational attainment and job status as well as household income. The chart compares the average performance of children in the top fifth of the socioeconomic status distribution (high-SES) with the average performance of children in the bottom fifth (low-SES). Skills measured include reading and math and self-control and approaches to learning as reported by teachers. High-SES children score significantly higher in reading and math than their low-SES peers; gaps in both subjects are larger than a full standard deviation. High-SES children also score significantly higher on social and emotional skills, though the gaps are smaller (about one-third to one-half a standard deviation).

Though not reflected in the chart, these gaps are about as wide as they were for the last generation of kindergartners. These education inequalities not only threaten children’s development during their school years but shortchange them by lowering their economic prospects later in life. The lack of true equality of opportunity calls for a shift from blaming schools and teachers for achievement gaps that begin before school starts and that largely persist as children move through school. Instead we should be advancing comprehensive education policies that address the poverty and social inequalities that are the real drivers of low economic performance, and pursuing economic policies that address the broader structural forces that drive poverty and inequality and hold back our children.

Share this chart:

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

City governments are raising standards for working people—but too often state legislators are lowering them back down: Map of states using preemption laws to block local governments from raising pay and other standards for working people

12
City governments are raising standards for working people—but too often state legislators are lowering them back down: Map of states using preemption laws to block local governments from raising pay and other standards for working people

Twenty-six states have laws on the books that prohibit cities and counties from enacting policies that raise standards for working people. The map shows the states with such “preemption” laws, and which of the five key worker rights the preemption laws target. In law, the term “preemption” refers to situations in which a law passed by a higher government authority, such as a state legislature, supersedes a law passed by a lower one, such as an ordinance passed by a city council. What the map doesn’t show is the proliferation of preemption laws since the turn of the century, particularly in the last five years. This same map in 2000 would have highlighted only Louisiana and Colorado, which preempted local governments from enacting higher minimum wages. In 2012, the map would have highlighted an additional eight states, with most preempting local minimum wage laws and/or local paid leave laws. In 2013, the number of states with preemption laws tackling other worker rights began its steady ascent.

Today, cities, counties, and other local governments in 25 states can’t set minimum wages higher than the state minimum wage. Local governments in 21 states can’t require that local employers offer paid sick leave or other forms of paid family or medical leave. Local governments in nine states can’t require that employers provide workers with advance notice of work hours or compensation for last-minute schedule changes. Local governments in seven states can’t require that employers with government contracts pay at least the local median wage for the given type of work. And local governments in six states can’t pursue project labor agreements that set basic conditions for worker safety and pay when building roads, bridges, or other municipal infrastructure.

What happened after 2010 to cover the map in red? While waiting for state and federal governments to act, local governments (such as cities and counties) began taking action to raise working conditions in their communities. Before 2012, only five localities had enacted their own local minimum wage laws, but as of 2017, 40 counties and cities have done so. Republicans in control of all branches of state government in a number of states pivoted to state preemption laws to lower those standards back down. A corporate-backed lobbying group, the American Legislative Exchange Council (ALEC), had model preemption laws with sample legislative language ready to adapt. The rapid spread of preemption followed, with the number of states with such laws more than doubling from 10 in 2012 to 26 in 2017, and the number of preemption laws more than quadrupling, from 15 to 67.

Share this chart:

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.