Report | Raising America's Pay

Inequality is slowing U.S. economic growth: Faster wage growth for low- and middle-wage workers is the solution

Raising America's Pay

Download PDF

Press release

What this report finds: Income inequality in the United States is suppressing growth in aggregate demand (spending by households, businesses, and governments) by shifting an ever larger share of income to rich households that save rather than spend. This rise in inequality has been overwhelmingly driven by the failure of pay for typical American workers to keep pace with economywide productivity growth. EPI estimates that rising inequality has slowed growth in aggregate demand by 2 to 4 percentage points of GDP annually in recent years.

Why it matters: For decades, the drag on demand growth stemming from rising inequality has been compensated for by other economic and policy developments—notably a long-running decline in interest rates. Going forward, however, these compensating mechanisms are likely to fail, which means that the inequality-induced drag on demand would translate directly into slower economic growth overall.

What we can do about it: In the near term, we need more expansionary macroeconomic policies—lower interest rates and larger budget deficits—to counter the downward pressure on demand. In the longer run, we need to stop or reverse rising inequality by enacting policies that spur faster wage growth for low- and middle-wage workers. Raising these workers’ wages would not only raise living standards for American families, it would also ensure robust economic growth.


Executive summary

Income inequality in the United States has risen dramatically since the late 1970s, and the issue has drawn heightened attention in recent years. In the past decade, economic observers have also become increasingly worried about “secular stagnation”—or a chronic shortfall of aggregate demand, fearing that this shortfall will constrain American economic growth in coming years. These two phenomena—rising inequality and chronic weakness of demand—are related. Specifically, rising inequality transfers income from low-saving households in the bottom and middle of the income distribution to higher-saving households at the top. All else equal, this redistribution away from low- to high-saving households reduces consumption spending, which drags on demand growth.

This paper argues that a key lever for solving the problem of secular stagnation is halting, or even reversing, the root cause of rising inequality: the growing wedge between productivity and pay for typical American workers. Following are our key findings:

  • A stunningly large upward redistribution of income has characterized the American economy in recent decades. In 1979, the bottom 90 percent of American households claimed roughly 70 percent of total income in the U.S. economy. By 2016, this share had fallen to around 60 percent.
  • By far the most important driver of this upward redistribution is the growing wedge between economy-wide productivity growth (a measure of income generated in an average hour of work in the United States) and hourly pay of typical American workers since the mid-1970s. Had these two measures grown together the way they did in earlier eras, there would have been no possibility of upward income redistribution.
  • A strong and growing body of macroeconomic evidence shows that the U.S. economy needs lower and lower interest rates simply to provide the same growth of aggregate demand over time. In short, something is pushing down the growth rate of aggregate demand, and macroeconomic policies need to become more and more expansionary in each successive year simply to hold demand constant. This development has sometimes been labeled “secular stagnation.”

The rise in inequality has contributed significantly to the downward pressure on demand growth that is labeled secular stagnation. Inequality has transferred income from low- and middle-income households with relatively low savings rates towards higher-income households with higher savings rates. All else equal, this transfer drags on demand growth as consumption grows more slowly. This transfer will likely slow growth in aggregate demand by an estimated 2 to 4 percentage points of gross domestic product (GDP) every year going forward from today. 1

  • The demand drag imposed each year by rising inequality is equivalent to the peak boost to economic demand provided (in 2010) by the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA, the stimulus package passed in the first months of the Obama administration). Essentially to offset the hit to demand posed by rising inequality, we’d need to enact a policy each and every year that delivers a boost of the rough magnitude of the peak ARRA boost.
  • One puzzle that arises in the causal chain linking rising inequality to slower demand growth is that the personal savings rate measured in the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) has actually declined, not risen over recent decades. However, a closer analysis of the data and economics behind savings behavior shows that the declining savings rate measured conventionally in the NIPAs does not capture many ways in which savings of high-income households have increased. The most important fact is that unrealized capital gains spurred by corporate stock buybacks are not captured in the NIPA personal savings measure. However, these unrealized gains do constitute large increases in wealth (which is a form of savings) for shareholders.

Introduction

The problem of anemic wage growth—recognized for decades by American workers wishing for higher paychecks—has finally reached the front-burner of American politics. Angst over the stagnant pay of low-wage workers has for example, sparked recent movements to raise minimum federal, state, and local minimum wages far above levels that have characterized the recent past, and often even to levels that would constitute historical highs.2

This new attention to the crisis of American pay is totally proper. The failure of wages of the vast majority of Americans to benefit from economy-wide growth in productivity (or income generated in an average hour of work) has been the root cause of the stratospheric rise in inequality and the concentration of economic growth at the very top of the income distribution. Had this upward redistribution not happened, incomes for the bottom 90 percent of Americans would be roughly 20 percent higher today.3 In short, the rise in inequality driven by anemic wage growth has imposed an “inequality tax” on American households that has robbed them of a fifth of their potential income.

There would be huge benefits to American well-being from blocking or reversing this upward redistribution. This welfare gain stemming from blocking upward redistribution is the primary reason to champion policy measures to boost wage growth and lead to a more equal distribution of income gains. Put simply, a dollar is worth more to a family living paycheck to paycheck than it is to families comfortably in the top 1 percent of the income distribution.

Proponents of increases in the minimum wage and other measures to boost American wages have often argued that there are benefits to these policies besides the welfare gains stemming from pure redistribution. These proponents have often argued that boosting wages would even benefit aggregate economic outcomes, like growth in gross domestic product (GDP) or employment.

Recent evidence about developments in the American and global economies strongly indicate that these arguments are correct: boosting wages of the bottom 90 percent would not just raise these households’ incomes and welfare (a more-than-sufficient reason to do so), it would also boost overall growth. For the past decade (and maybe even longer), the primary constraint on American economic growth has been too-slow spending by households, businesses, and governments. In economists’ jargon, the constraint has been growth in aggregate demand lagging behind growth in the economy’s productive capacity (including growth of the labor force and the stock of productive capital, such as plants and equipment). Much research indicates that this shortfall of demand could become a chronic problem in the future, constantly pulling down growth unless macroeconomic policy changes dramatically.

Our rising inequality is being driven by the slowdown in wage growth for the bottom 90 percent

It is now well-known that incomes in America grew much less equally after 1979. Probably the most important fact about this growing inequality is that it has overwhelmingly been driven by trends in market-based income rather than in the taxes and transfers component of income. Table 1 shows the sources of income growth for the top 1 percent of households in the three decades before the Great Recession. It uses Congressional Budget Office (CBO 2016) data on comprehensive household income, which includes noncash market-based income such as employer contributions to health insurance premiums as well as non–market-based income such as government transfers. The CBO data show that inequality is increasing (the share of all income that is going to the top is rising) because the top 1 percent are getting a greater share of each type of market income and because the types of market income that are most concentrated at the top (particularly capital gains and business income) constitute a growing share of all income, whereas income from less-concentrated sources (particularly labor compensation) is falling as a share of overall income. The data in the table also indicate that the direct, arithmetic influence of taxes and transfers has been minimal, with rising inequality of market incomes explaining more than 100 percent of the rise in the after-tax income share of the top 1 percent.4

Table 1

All types of market incomes are increasingly concentrated at the top: Changes in top 1 percent income shares, by income category, and contribution of growing concentration to increasing top 1 percent share

Total capital and business income
Total Labor compensation Rents, interest, dividends Business income Capital gains Total Pensions Transfers
Top 1% share of each income type
1979 8.9% 4.3% 27.0% 22.5% 61.4% 34.0% 5.2% 1.0%
2007 18.7% 9.3% 44.4% 52.5% 77.3% 60.0% 7.4% 1.0
2012 17.3% 9.3% 48.8% 52.8% 85.6% 61.7% 9.8% 0.9%
Each income type’s share of overall income
1979 100.0% 70.6% 8.1% 4.5% 4.9% 17.5% 3.2% 8.8%
2007 100.0% 61.0% 6.9% 6.2% 9.0% 22.1% 6.3% 10.6%
2012 100.0% 61.0% 5.3% 7.1% 5.9% 18.4% 6.9% 13.8%
Within contributions*
1979–2007 7.2 3.2 1.3 1.6 1.1 4.0 0.1 0.0
2007–2012 8.0 3.3 1.5 1.8 1.3 4.5 0.2 0.0
Between contributions**
1979–2007 2.6 -0.6 -0.4 0.6 2.8 3.0 0.2 0.0
2007–2012 0.4 -0.6 -1.1 1.0 0.8 0.7 0.3 0.0

* Percentage-point contribution of growing concentration within each income category to increasing top 1% income share

** Percentage-point contribution of shift from less- to more-concentrated income categories to increasing top 1% income share

Source: Author's analysis of Congressional Budget Office (2016)

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

The first block of columns simply shows the top 1 percent share of overall household income and of various income types as identified in CBO (2016). A clear finding is that the top 1 percent share of every source of income except government transfers rose significantly between 1979 and 2007. The share of overall income held by the top 1 percent more than doubles (rising from 8.9 to 18.7 percent of total income) between 1979 and 2007. And even with the enormous blow to top 1 percent incomes dealt by the 40 percent loss in the stock market from 2007 to 2010, the top 1 percent share in 2012 of 17.3 percent was almost double its 1979 level. Particularly salient to this analysis is the rough doubling of both labor and total capital shares claimed by the top 1 percent from 1979 to 2007 and 2012.

The next block of columns shows each income category’s share of overall household income. The most striking finding here is the large decline in the labor compensation share of total income, falling from 70.6 percent in 1979 to 61.0 percent in 2007 and 2012. Correspondingly, the share of total capital and business income (driven by capital gains and business income) rose substantially, from 17.5 percent in 1979 to 22.1 percent in 2007.5 Due to the stock market crash in 2007 and the hangover from that crash through 2010, capital income shares (and thus total capital and business income) remained lower in 2012 than in 2007, but still above the 1979 levels. Finally, pension payments and transfer incomes have risen steadily over time as shares of total income.

The third block of columns calculates how much growing concentration within each income category contributed to the increasing top 1 percent share of income from 1979 to 2007 and from 1979 to 2012. The growing concentration of particular income types in the top 1 percent of households contributed 7.2 percentage points to the 9.8 percentage-point increase in the top 1 percent’s income share from 1979 to 2007, accounting for essentially three quarters of the rise. The vast majority of this concentration within income sources is accounted for by labor and capital incomes. The last block of columns summarizes how much the shift from less-concentrated (labor) income to more-concentrated (capital) incomes boosted the top 1 percent share of overall household income. The sum of these shifts contributed 2.6 percentage points to the growth of the top 1 percent share from 1979 to 2007, and 0.4 percentage points from 2007 to 2012.

One way to summarize what these data tell us is that the vast majority of households (those outside the top 1 percent) are losing out in claiming their proportionate share of total income growth in two significant ways. First, workers as a group are losing out to capital owners, with the shift from labor to capital income explaining a significant portion of the rise of the top 1 percent. Second, the bottom 99 percent of income earners in America are able to claim only an ever-shrinking portion of the overall wage bill, with the highest-paid workers in the top 1 percent more than doubling their share of labor income over the last three and a half decades.

In our view, these are simply two sides of the same coin: a pronounced reduction in the collective and individual bargaining power of ordinary American workers that led to pay growth lagging productivity so badly in recent decades. If wages of the bottom 99 percent had kept pace with productivity growth for most of the past generation (the way that typical workers’ wages did in the post-WWII generation), then most of the increase in income inequality we have seen simply would not have had space to develop, as concentration within labor incomes would not have grown and the share of total output available to be claimed by capital owners would have been significantly smaller.6

But wages for the vast majority of workers stopped keeping pace with economy-wide productivity growth in the late 1970s, and the cumulative wedge between productivity and typical workers’ pay has risen ever since, as shown below in Figure A. This figure shows growth in economy-wide productivity, defined as the amount of income and output generated in an average hour of work in the economy. While the pace of productivity growth slowed down in the late 1970s, productivity still grew steadily in the following decades. The figure also shows a measure of hourly pay (including both wages and benefits) for production and nonsupervisory workers in the U.S. economy. This nonmanagerial group includes roughly 80 percent of the private-sector workforce. After growing right in line with productivity for decades following World War II, hourly pay for these workers all but stagnated after 1979. Because productivity kept growing but pay for 80 percent of the private-sector workforce stagnated, this means that the economy continued to generate growing incomes on average each year, but pay for typical workers slowed radically. In short, the growing wedge between these lines represents the disproportionate share of economic growth claimed by those at the top after 1979.

Figure A

The gap between productivity and a typical worker's compensation has increased dramatically since 1973: Productivity growth and hourly compensation growth, 1948–2016

Year Hourly compensation Productivity
1948  0.00% 0.00%
1949 6.25% 1.55%
1950 10.48% 9.33%
1951 11.76% 12.35%
1952 15.04% 15.63%
1953 20.85% 19.55%
1954 23.52% 21.56%
1955 28.74% 26.46%
1956 33.95% 26.66%
1957 37.14% 30.09%
1958 38.16% 32.78%
1959 42.55% 37.64%
1960 45.50% 40.05%
1961 47.99% 44.36%
1962 52.48% 49.79%
1963 55.03% 55.01%
1964 58.51% 59.99%
1965 62.47% 64.94%
1966 64.90% 70.00%
1967 66.90% 72.05%
1968 70.74% 77.16%
1969 74.67% 77.88%
1970 76.61% 80.37%
1971 82.02% 87.10%
1972 91.25% 92.05%
1973  91.31% 96.75%
1974 86.98% 93.66%
1975 86.86% 97.92%
1976 89.68% 103.44%
1977 93.15% 105.79%
1978 95.98% 107.79%
1979 93.45% 108.14%
1980 88.59% 106.57%
1981 87.61% 111.02%
1982 87.79% 107.88%
1983 88.37% 114.13%
1984 86.96% 119.73%
1985 86.33% 123.43%
1986 87.34% 127.99%
1987 84.62% 129.12%
1988 83.87%   131.78%
1989 83.72% 133.65%
1990 82.24% 136.98%
1991 81.90% 138.89%
1992 83.07% 147.56%
1993 83.41% 148.37%
1994 83.84% 150.75%
1995 82.73% 150.86%
1996 82.81% 156.92%
1997 84.82% 160.50%
1998 89.19% 165.71%
1999 91.94% 172.08%
2000 92.92% 178.50% 
2001 95.59% 182.84%
2002 99.40% 190.72%
2003 101.66% 200.17%
2004 100.87% 208.21%
2005 100.07% 213.58%
2006 100.24% 215.48%
2007 101.73% 217.70%
2008 101.74% 218.24%
2009 109.72% 224.75%
2010 111.56% 234.28%
2011 109.09% 234.67%
2012 107.30% 236.51%
2013 108.34% 237.57%
2014 109.22% 239.30%
2015 112.81% 241.08%
2016 115.14%  241.76% 
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Data are for compensation (wages and benefits) of production/nonsupervisory workers in the private sector and net productivity of the total economy. "Net productivity" is the growth of output of goods and services less depreciation per hour worked. Shaded area's denote recessions.

Source: EPI analysis of Bureau of Labor Statistics and Bureau of Economic Analysis data. Updated from Figure A in Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s Our Central Economic Policy Challenge (Bivens et al. 2014)

Source: EPI analysis of unpublished Total Economy Productivity data from Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) Labor Productivity and Costs program, wage data from the BLS Current Employment Statistics, BLS Employment Cost Trends, BLS Consumer Price Index, and Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Product Accounts

Updated from: Figure A in Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s Our Central Economic Policy Challenge, by Josh Bivens, Elise Gould, Lawrence Mishel, and Heidi Shierholz, Economic Policy Institute, 2014.

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Table 1 and Figure A together tell a clear story about the rise in American inequality: it has been made possible by the suppression of wage growth for the vast majority of American workers. Until this wage suppression ends and hourly pay for the vast majority of workers begins rising in lockstep with economy-wide productivity, there is very little reason to hope that rising inequality can be arrested. This makes focusing policy attention on boosting wage growth absolutely crucial.

“Secular stagnation,” or, the chronic shortage of aggregate demand constraining economic growth

A useful (if admittedly too-simple) way to think about an economy’s growth is as an interplay between the economy’s productive capacity and the level of aggregate demand. The economy’s productive capacity is a measure of potential that includes three major “inputs” of production: the labor force, the capital stock, and the state of technology. However, for these potential inputs to be fully utilized, aggregate demand—or spending by households, businesses, and governments—must be strong enough to mobilize them. Take the example of a hotel’s economic fortunes from 2007 to 2010. In 2007, the building and physical plant existed, the systems for taking reservations existed, and there were plenty of workers, both actual employees and potential workers willing to take jobs at the right wages. Also in that year, there were customers; rooms were likely booked to capacity and the owners may have even considered adding rooms. In 2010, this hotel still had a physical plant and reservation systems, and while their own staff was likely much smaller because of layoffs in the wake of the Great Recession, there was a huge increase in potential workers looking for jobs that could have been hired. But what kept the hotel’s hiring constrained and profits low in 2010 was lack of customers, not slow growth in the economy’s potential (or productive capacity).

Recently, a number of economists have noted that evidence over recent decades indicates that growth has been constrained more by slow growth in aggregate demand than by slow growth in the economy’s productive capacity. For example, the full business cycle between the peaks of 2001 and 2007 saw the slowest economic growth then on record. The result of this slow growth was that the unemployment rate never returned to prerecession levels, and the prime-age employment-to-population (EPOP) ratio never approached prerecession levels. (See Bivens and Irons 2008 for a full accounting of this business cycle’s place in historical comparisons.) All of this indicates that the slow growth that took hold even before the Great Recession hit was likely a function of too-slow growth in aggregate demand—or spending by households, businesses, and governments.

Before the Great Recession, most macroeconomists would have rejected the idea that economic growth could be constrained for long periods of time by too-slow demand growth relative to the economy’s productive capacity. The typical view was that growth in productive capacity was driven by long-run trends that did not change very fast, such as the aging of the population (which determines the pace of potential labor force growth), the accumulation of plants, equipment, and buildings that is the result of decades of past investment, and accelerations and decelerations of technology that were largely exogenous (unrelated to the state of the business cycle). In this view, ensuring that growth in productive capacity (or growth in potential GDP) is fully realized essentially means ensuring that aggregate demand grows quickly enough to keep resources (labor and capital) fully employed.

In past decades, policymakers considered it relatively easy to keep aggregate demand growing fast enough high enough to fully utilize the economy’s productive capacity. In fact, macroeconomic policymakers thought their most difficult task was restraining, not boosting, growth in aggregate demand. When aggregate demand for economic output outstrips the economy’s productive capacity to meet that demand, the result is inflation. So policymakers focused on controlling inflation—or ensuring that aggregate demand did not run chronically too fast. Of course, the U.S. economy underwent recessions during which demand growth lagged behind potential GDP growth, but it was thought that the demand shortfalls could be easily solved by the Federal Reserve reducing short-term interest rates to spur more spending. Because aggregate demand was thought to need policy restraint, not stimulus, this implies that overall growth was constrained by how fast the economy’s productive capacity could grow. Any worry that persistently slow growth (say lasting more than one year) in aggregate demand could be a primary constraint on economic growth over a meaningfully long time period was largely dismissed. We now know that this dismissal was premature, and that sluggish demand growth can pull down economic growth for long periods of time.

The data show we are in such a period, and likely have been for over a decade. The extraordinarily weak GDP growth between 2001 and 2007 was accompanied by decelerating wage growth, and low inflation and interest rates. These trends are strong indicators that demand was lagging growth in productive capacity. This weakness in demand was especially striking given that aggregate demand (or spending by households, businesses, and governments) was buoyed in those years initially by near-zero interest rates (set by the Federal Reserve in the early 2000s) and then by an enormous asset bubble in residential real estate that increased household wealth in the mid-2000s. The housing bubble burst, ushering in the Great Recession. The recovery from that recession was even slower than the recovery from the 2001 recession, despite extraordinarily expansionary monetary policy in the wake of the Great Recession.

Figure B shows the ratio of actual GDP to potential GDP since 1995. When this ratio is below 1, there is prima facie evidence that aggregate demand is constraining economic growth. As the figure shows, this ratio has been well below 1 for most of the past two decades, even as monetary policy has been historically expansionary.

Figure B

Lagging demand is holding back economic growth: Ratio of actual to potential GDP, 1995–2016

Date Output gap Actual and potential GDP are equal
1995Q1 0.977097% 1%
1995Q2 0.973481 1
1995Q3 0.97466 1
1995Q4 0.974352 1
1996Q1 0.97351 1
1996Q2 0.982895 1
1996Q3 0.984196 1
1996Q4 0.986468 1
1997Q1 0.985363 1
1997Q2 0.991033 1
1997Q3 0.994141 1
1997Q4 0.992155 1
1998Q1 0.992044 1
1998Q2 0.991505 1
1998Q3 0.99416 1
1998Q4 1.000036 1
1999Q1 0.997827 1
1999Q2 0.995959 1
1999Q3 0.998422 1
1999Q4 1.005654 1
2000Q1 0.998923 1
2000Q2 1.00783 1
2000Q3 0.999553 1
2000Q4 0.995967 1
2001Q1 0.984363 1
2001Q2 0.981188 1
2001Q3 0.970231 1
2001Q4 0.965416 1
2002Q1 0.967249 1
2002Q2 0.965966 1
2002Q3 0.964341 1
2002Q4 0.958892 1
2003Q1 0.957809 1
2003Q2 0.960716 1
2003Q3 0.97076 1
2003Q4 0.976107 1
2004Q1 0.97571 1
2004Q2 0.976673 1
2004Q3 0.979341 1
2004Q4 0.981633 1
2005Q1 0.98591 1
2005Q2 0.985075 1
2005Q3 0.987495 1
2005Q4 0.987516 1
2006Q1 0.994037 1
2006Q2 0.992109 1
2006Q3 0.988332 1
2006Q4 0.991479 1
2007Q1 0.987713 1
2007Q2 0.990828 1
2007Q3 0.993133 1
2007Q4 0.992421 1
2008Q1 0.98154 1
2008Q2 0.982149 1
2008Q3 0.973463 1
2008Q4 0.949394 1
2009Q1 0.933047 1
2009Q2 0.928985 1
2009Q3 0.929432 1
2009Q4 0.935965 1
2010Q1 0.937864 1
2010Q2 0.944765 1
2010Q3 0.949017 1
2010Q4 0.952779 1
2011Q1 0.946651 1
2011Q2 0.950835 1
2011Q3 0.950052 1
2011Q4 0.957724 1
2012Q1 0.960962 1
2012Q2 0.962196 1
2012Q3 0.960011 1
2012Q4 0.956805 1
2013Q1 0.959872 1
2013Q2 0.958077 1
2013Q3 0.961676 1
2013Q4 0.967167 1
2014Q1 0.96119 1
2014Q2 0.968049 1
2014Q3 0.976319 1
2014Q4 0.977145 1
2015Q1 0.980831 1
2015Q2 0.983327 1
2015Q3 0.983191 1
2015Q4 0.980332 1
2016Q1 0.977782 1
2016Q2 0.979279 1
2016Q3 0.982089 1
2016Q4 0.982508 1
2017Q1 0.9817 1
2017Q2 0.985229% 1%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Potential GDP is adjusted to make 1999 a year with no output gap (a ratio of 1 on this chart). This adjustment is based on a low and non-accelerating rate of inflation in that year. Shaded areas denote recessions.

Source: Author’s analysis of data from CBO (2017)

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Weakness in aggregate demand since 2008 has likely degraded growth in the economy’s productive capacity

Aggregate demand growth has lagged growth in the economy’s productive capacity over much of the last two decades even as growth in this productive capacity itself slowed sharply. Crucially, there is ample evidence that the degraded growth in potential output is itself another casualty of too-slack demand. It is now well-known that changes in productive capacity (i.e., the supply side of the economy) are likely affected by changes in the demand-side of the economy. The most obvious example concerns capital investment. When demand is weak, customers disappear and workers’ wages don’t grow as fast, or grow at all, as rising unemployment crushes workers’ bargaining power. A shortage of customers and weak wage growth blunts the incentive of firms to invest in plants or equipment to expand capacity or save on labor costs. This in turn slows the growth of the economy’s capital stock, a key input in its productive capacity. Short recessions will leave only a small scar on an economy’s productive capacity, but there is now ample evidence that longer and steeper recessions can do serious damage to even the economy’s potential, let alone actual, growth. We have clearly seen this dynamic over the past decade.7 Growth in potential GDP has been so much slower than growth that was projected in 2008 for the next decade that forecasters by 2017 have essentially erased $2 trillion annually in potential output from the American economy, as shown in Figure C.

Figure C

Lagging demand from Great Recession has also hurt economy's potential growth: Actual GDP and estimates of potential GDP, 2001–2016Q3

Date 2008 estimate of potential 2017 estimate of potential Actual
2001Q1 85.34537 86.53812 85.91008
2001Q2 86.06692 87.28146 86.36534
2001Q3 86.76844 87.99891 86.09218
2001Q4 87.44473 88.68842 86.33136
2002Q1 88.0923 89.33365 87.12636
2002Q2 88.7181 89.94686 87.60677
2002Q3 89.3265 90.53894 88.03349
2002Q4 89.92358 91.11671 88.0892
2003Q1 90.51718 91.69381 88.54582
2003Q2 91.1073 92.26136 89.36733
2003Q3 91.69742 92.82551 90.86424
2003Q4 92.29015 93.39034 91.92629
2004Q1 92.88723 93.96607 92.45493
2004Q2 93.49215 94.5602 93.13239
2004Q3 94.10577 95.15705 93.97903
2004Q4 94.72722 95.75322 94.7917
2005Q1 95.35912 96.34939 95.80211
2005Q2 96.00059 96.93534 96.30221
2005Q3 96.65077 97.50767 97.11148
2005Q4 97.30878 98.06227 97.66595
2006Q1 97.97288 98.58214 98.83943
2006Q2 98.64307 99.07134 99.13501
2006Q3 99.31849 99.54282 99.22334
2006Q4 100 100 100
2007Q1 100.685 100.4476 100.0618
2007Q2 101.3761 100.8946 100.8276
2007Q3 102.0706 101.3347 101.5058
2007Q4 102.7696 101.7701 101.8679
2008Q1 103.4711 102.2089 101.1728
2008Q2 104.1735 102.6518 101.6749
2008Q3 104.8768 103.081 101.1871
2008Q4 105.5809 103.4898 99.04939
2009Q1 106.2842 103.8632 97.67682
2009Q2 106.9874 104.1814 97.545
2009Q3 107.6916 104.4709 97.86368
2009Q4 108.3966 104.738 98.81089
2010Q1 109.1025 104.9758 99.23829
2010Q2 109.8083 105.2075 100.1971
2010Q3 110.5168 105.4384 100.8738
2010Q4 111.2279 105.679 101.5091
2011Q1 111.9443 105.9597 101.1171
2011Q2 112.6675 106.256 101.853
2011Q3 113.3969 106.5681 102.067
2011Q4 114.1333 106.8958 103.2167
2012Q1 114.8766 107.2379 103.901
2012Q2 115.6251 107.599 104.3861
2012Q3 116.378 107.9757 104.5111
2012Q4 117.1335 108.3662 104.5349
2013Q1 117.889 108.7715 105.2661
2013Q2 118.6453 109.1865 105.4679
2013Q3 119.4008 109.6123 106.2812
2013Q4 120.1563 110.0463 107.3181
2014Q1 120.9118 110.4838 107.0715
2014Q2 121.6656 110.9328 108.2823
2014Q3 122.4193 111.3886 109.6664
2014Q4 123.1722 111.8498 110.2148
2015Q1 123.9259 112.3165 111.0968
2015Q2 124.6788 112.788 111.8503
2015Q3 125.4335 113.2609 112.3035
2015Q4 126.1898 113.7324 112.4394
2016Q1 126.9488 114.1977 112.6025
2016Q2 127.7104 114.6535 113.227
2016Q3 128.4754 115.108 114.0057
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Shaded areas denote recession. Measures of potential output are from the 2008 and 2017 editions of the CBO Budget and Economic Outlook.

Source: Author’s analysis of data from BEA NIPA Table 1.1.6 and the Congressional Budget Office (on gross domestic product)

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

If even one quarter of this slowing growth in potential GDP is a function of sluggish demand growth affecting the course of the economy (in economists’ terms, imposing “hysteresis” effects), then the failure to boost demand to grow in tandem with potential GDP has been an economic calamity, costing $500 billion annually.8 Given these stakes, a number of researchers have begun looking into this chronic shortage of demand. Some have labeled this “secular stagnation,” which has unfortunately confused many people, including many economists, by obscuring that this is an argument about aggregate demand, not potential GDP. (Summers 2016 and Krugman 2013 offer some of the clearest statements about the problem of “secular stagnation.”) Recently, the same phenomenon has been recast as a fall in the economy’s “natural” or “neutral” rate of interest. This has also been referred to as the fall in “R-star” or R*, referencing how this natural or neutral rate of interest is often notated in economics papers.9

Lowering interest rates has been our coping mechanism for slow demand growth

The relationship between a chronic shortage of aggregate demand (secular stagnation) and the fall in the economy’s “neutral” interest rate is straightforward. A decline in aggregate demand growth that is exogenous to interest rates will generally spur the Federal Reserve to reduce interest rates in order to stimulate consumption and investment and keep the economy at full employment. Hence, the interest rate consistent with the economy reaching full employment (the neutral rate) will fall over time if this exogenous drag on demand growth continues or worsens.

The evidence that this neutral rate has declined over time is compelling. Figure D shows the federal funds rate (FFR) as well as showing its average value over recent business cycles. The evidence that the neutral FFR rate has been steadily falling since the 1980s seems quite clear.

Figure D

Clear decline in interest rates signals Fed is coping with slowing demand growth: Effective federal funds rate, actual and business cycle averages, 1960–2016

Year FFR 1960-1969 1969-1979 1979-1989  1989-2000  2000-2007  2007-2016 
1960Q1 2.70% 4.18
1960Q2 3.04 4.18
1960Q3 3.24 4.18
1960Q4 3.26 4.18
1961Q1 3.19 4.18
1961Q2 3.02 4.18
1961Q3 2.78 4.18
1961Q4 2.59 4.18
1962Q1 2.40 4.18
1962Q2 2.27 4.18
1962Q3 2.25 4.18
1962Q4 2.33 4.18
1963Q1 2.45 4.18
1963Q2 2.61 4.18
1963Q3 2.81 4.18
1963Q4 2.94 4.18
1964Q1 3.07 4.18
1964Q2 3.18 4.18
1964Q3 3.26 4.18
1964Q4 3.34 4.18
1965Q1 3.46 4.18
1965Q2 3.60 4.18
1965Q3 3.70 4.18
1965Q4 3.79 4.18
1966Q1 3.92 4.18
1966Q2 4.10 4.18
1966Q3 4.34 4.18
1966Q4 4.59 4.18
1967Q1 4.70 4.18
1967Q2 4.69 4.18
1967Q3 4.66 4.18
1967Q4 4.66 4.18
1968Q1 4.69 4.18
1968Q2 4.83 4.18
1968Q3 4.89 4.18
1968Q4 4.94 4.18
1969Q1 5.16 4.18
1969Q2 5.70 4.18
1969Q3 6.34 4.18
1969Q4 6.93 4.18
1970Q1 7.40 7.10325
1970Q2 7.64 7.10325
1970Q3 7.74 7.10325
1970Q4 7.69 7.10325
1971Q1 7.35 7.10325
1971Q2 6.88 7.10325
1971Q3 6.44 7.10325
1971Q4 5.92 7.10325
1972Q1 5.29 7.10325
1972Q2 4.84 7.10325
1972Q3 4.60 7.10325
1972Q4 4.55 7.10325
1973Q1 4.88 7.10325
1973Q2 5.29 7.10325
1973Q3 5.92 7.10325
1973Q4 6.58 7.10325
1974Q1 7.30 7.10325
1974Q2 8.17 7.10325
1974Q3 9.09 7.10325
1974Q4 9.62 7.10325
1975Q1 9.59 7.10325
1975Q2 9.29 7.10325
1975Q3 8.74 7.10325
1975Q4 8.16 7.10325
1976Q1 7.60 7.10325
1976Q2 6.85 7.10325
1976Q3 5.99 7.10325
1976Q4 5.43 7.10325
1977Q1 5.23 7.10325
1977Q2 5.20 7.10325
1977Q3 5.15 7.10325
1977Q4 5.29 7.10325
1978Q1 5.53 7.10325
1978Q2 5.79 7.10325
1978Q3 6.15 7.10325
1978Q4 6.73 7.10325
1979Q1 7.41 7.10325
1979Q2 8.04 7.10325
1979Q3 8.68 7.10325
1979Q4 9.56 7.10325
1980Q1 10.60 10.0775
1980Q2 11.28 10.0775
1980Q3 11.49 10.0775
1980Q4 12.28 10.0775
1981Q1 13.09 10.0775
1981Q2 14.04 10.0775
1981Q3 14.87 10.0775
1981Q4 14.87 10.0775
1982Q1 14.77 10.0775
1982Q2 14.99 10.0775
1982Q3 15.14 10.0775
1982Q4 14.32 10.0775
1983Q1 13.33 10.0775
1983Q2 12.21 10.0775
1983Q3 11.19 10.0775
1983Q4 10.67 10.0775
1984Q1 10.11 10.0775
1984Q2 9.61 10.0775
1984Q3 9.66 10.0775
1984Q4 9.66 10.0775
1985Q1 9.64 10.0775
1985Q2 9.53 10.0775
1985Q3 9.33 10.0775
1985Q4 9.16 10.0775
1986Q1 8.93 10.0775
1986Q2 8.48 10.0775
1986Q3 7.83 10.0775
1986Q4 7.45 10.0775
1987Q1 7.17 10.0775
1987Q2 7.01 10.0775
1987Q3 6.88 10.0775
1987Q4 6.73 10.0775
1988Q1 6.59 10.0775
1988Q2 6.62 10.0775
1988Q3 6.84 10.0775
1988Q4 7.11 10.0775
1989Q1 7.52 10.0775
1989Q2 7.90 10.0775
1989Q3 8.18 10.0775
1989Q4 8.39 10.0775
1990Q1 8.59 5.575
1990Q2 8.73 5.575
1990Q3 8.75 5.575
1990Q4 8.66 5.575
1991Q1 8.28 5.575
1991Q2 7.80 5.575
1991Q3 7.37 5.575
1991Q4 6.89 5.575
1992Q1 6.36 5.575
1992Q2 5.81 5.575
1992Q3 5.19 5.575
1992Q4 4.61 5.575
1993Q1 4.18 5.575
1993Q2 3.82 5.575
1993Q3 3.50 5.575
1993Q4 3.27 5.575
1994Q1 3.17 5.575
1994Q2 3.19 5.575
1994Q3 3.35 5.575
1994Q4 3.61 5.575
1995Q1 3.96 5.575
1995Q2 4.34 5.575
1995Q3 4.68 5.575
1995Q4 5.02 5.575
1996Q1 5.29 5.575
1996Q2 5.45 5.575
1996Q3 5.55 5.575
1996Q4 5.57 5.575
1997Q1 5.50 5.575
1997Q2 5.44 5.575
1997Q3 5.41 5.575
1997Q4 5.38 5.575
1998Q1 5.40 5.575
1998Q2 5.43 5.575
1998Q3 5.46 5.575
1998Q4 5.41 5.575
1999Q1 5.34 5.575
1999Q2 5.24 5.575
1999Q3 5.19 5.575
1999Q4 5.16 5.575
2000Q1 5.18 5.575
2000Q2 5.28 5.575
2000Q3 5.40 5.575
2000Q4 5.60 5.575
2001Q1 5.71 3.433125
2001Q2 5.66 3.433125
2001Q3 5.46 3.433125
2001Q4 5.06 3.433125
2002Q1 4.57 3.433125
2002Q2 4.00 3.433125
2002Q3 3.41 3.433125
2002Q4 2.78 3.433125
2003Q1 2.23 3.433125
2003Q2 1.85 3.433125
2003Q3 1.54 3.433125
2003Q4 1.40 3.433125
2004Q1 1.31 3.433125
2004Q2 1.21 3.433125
2004Q3 1.18 3.433125
2004Q4 1.24 3.433125
2005Q1 1.39 3.433125
2005Q2 1.60 3.433125
2005Q3 1.91 3.433125
2005Q4 2.28 3.433125
2006Q1 2.71 3.433125
2006Q2 3.20 3.433125
2006Q3 3.68 3.433125
2006Q4 4.09 3.433125
2007Q1 4.44 3.433125
2007Q2 4.73 3.433125
2007Q3 4.93 3.433125
2007Q4 4.99 3.433125
2008Q1 4.83 0.382895
2008Q2 4.48 0.382895
2008Q3 4.07 0.382895
2008Q4 3.48 0.382895
2009Q1 2.84 0.382895
2009Q2 2.21 0.382895
2009Q3 1.59 0.382895
2009Q4 1.05 0.382895
2010Q1 0.66 0.382895
2010Q2 0.43 0.382895
2010Q3 0.21 0.382895
2010Q4 0.17 0.382895
2011Q1 0.17 0.382895
2011Q2 0.15 0.382895
2011Q3 0.14 0.382895
2011Q4 0.14 0.382895
2012Q1 0.13 0.382895
2012Q2 0.13 0.382895
2012Q3 0.12 0.382895
2012Q4 0.12 0.382895
2013Q1 0.12 0.382895
2013Q2 0.12 0.382895
2013Q3 0.12 0.382895
2013Q4 0.12 0.382895
2014Q1 0.12 0.382895
2014Q2 0.11 0.382895
2014Q3 0.11 0.382895
2014Q4 0.10 0.382895
2015Q1 0.09 0.382895
2015Q2 0.09 0.382895
2015Q3 0.10 0.382895
2015Q4 0.11 0.382895
2016Q1 0.15 0.382895
2016Q2 0.18 0.382895
2016Q3 0.22 0.382895
2016Q4 0.26 0.382895
2017Q1 0.34 0.382895
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Notes: Data are quarterly averages. Horizontal lines are averages over dates indicated. Shading indicates recessions.

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

The relationship between secular stagnation and inequality

There is a relatively straightforward causal link between the rise of inequality and the chronic shortfall of aggregate demand: higher-income households have much higher savings rates than low- and middle-income households. So, as a dollar is transferred from the bottom and middle to the top of the income distribution, less of it is spent.

When the economy is functioning well, reduced consumer spending is offset by increased investment in plants and equipment, and demand is hence unaffected. Here is how it could work. The reduced consumption stemming from this redistribution translates mechanically into higher savings. Higher savings in turn puts downward pressure on interest rates, and these lower interest rates induce more business investment in plants and equipment. This interest rate adjustment hence ensures that the reduced consumption spending that follows the upward redistribution of income is matched by an increase in investment spending, and hence does not constitute a drag on growth in aggregate demand.

The zero lower bound on interest rates means future drags on demand will translate into slowdowns in growth

Keeping demand growth constant in the face of upward redistribution of income requires ever-lower interest rates, consistent with the data highlighted above. But if this neutral rate falls far enough, the economy’s ability to seamlessly translate lower consumption (or higher savings) into higher investment spending will be potentially blocked by the zero lower bound (ZLB) on interest rates. Interest rates cannot be moved below zero (or at least not too much below zero) for extended periods of time because negative interest rates will just induce households to hold their wealth in cash rather than interest-bearing (or interest-subtracting!) bonds. With the economy’s ability to translate additional savings into higher investment blocked at the ZLB, further increases in savings will instead show up as unused capacity and output losses rather than interest rates reductions. Figure D showed that the U.S. economy has spent most of the post-2001 period hovering perilously close to the ZLB, so it is valid to fear that increases in inequality have dragged on growth and will continue to drag on growth.

How much is inequality sapping demand?

The previous section noted that rising inequality will, all else equal, slow demand growth, as income is transferred to higher-savings households at the top of the income distribution. The empirical question is just how much rising inequality has contributed to the decline in aggregate demand growth. Again, this decline in demand growth will show up in data as either a slowdown in overall growth, or a pronounced decline in the neutral interest rate. Rachel and Smith (2015), using a variety of techniques, estimate that the rise in inequality in recent decades will likely depress global interest rates by up to 0.6 percent in coming decades, making its importance on par with any other single influence they survey. They also note that while the global interest rate is important, country-specific rates can diverge from global rates due to country-specific factors. Given that the U.S. economy has seen a larger concentration of income at the top of the distribution than have other advanced countries, the effect of inequality on the pace of aggregate demand growth (and hence interest rates) is likely larger as well.

Cynamon and Fazzari (2015) assemble a range of indicators estimating the potential of both rising inequality and rising household debt to act as a brake on demand growth. They highlight the role of rising household debt as a buffer that kept consumption for the bottom 95 percent of households from falling in the face of relatively slow income growth in the pre-Great Recession period. This buffer was annihilated by the wealth lost when the housing bubble burst and ushered in the Great Recession in 2008. Cynamon and Fazzari (2015) argue that the decaying effect on demand of the transfer to the top, combined with the removal of the debt-consumption buffer, can largely explain the slow recovery from the Great Recession. These findings are largely buttressed by Alichi, Kantenga, and Sole (2016), who use a regression-based framework to estimate that changes in the American income distribution since 1998 had led to a demand-drag of more than 1 percent of total U.S. GDP by 2013.

A key component of an analysis of demand drag caused by rising inequality is the savings rate of rich households. Figure E is constructed in the spirit of Cynamon and Fazzari (2015), but makes some slightly different choices about income definitions and presentation of percentiles. It shows average savings rates, from 1989 to 2013, of the bottom four-fifths of the income distribution, as well as savings rates of households between the 80th and 90th percentiles, between the 90th and 95th percentiles, between the 95th and 99th percentiles, and of households in the top 1 percent. It replicates a procedure first identified by Maki and Palumbo (2001) to identify savings rates of the richest households. This procedure, and our adaption of it, uses the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) to calculate each income percentile’s share of various asset holdings. It then merges this SCF data on distribution with macroeconomic data from the Financial Accounts of the United States (FAUS), which shows the net acquisition of various types of assets. The assumption used is that if a given income group held, say, half of all Treasury bonds in a given year, then this group was also responsible for half of the aggregate net acquisition of those bonds in a given year. Multiplying each income group’s share of assets by the net acquisition of those assets and summing across all asset types provides an estimate of total assets acquired by each income group in a given year. This gives us a measure of total savings by income group in each year.10

Figure E

Higher-income households have much higher savings rates: Savings as share of income by income percentiles, 1989-2013 averages

Household Change in net worth
Average 11.5515%
Bottom 80 0.7921%
80th-90th 1.8521%
90th-95th 9.8394%
95th-99th 29.5229%
Top 1 47.4255%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Notes: Construction of the data is  described in the appendix.

Source: Author’s analysis of data from the Federal Reserve Board's Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF), the Federal Reserve Board's Financial Accounts of the United States (FAUS), and Congressional Budget Office data on household income and effective tax rates (CBO 2016)

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

For each group’s income, we again use data on comprehensive household income from the Congressional Budget Office (2016). Unlike Cynamon and Fazzari (2015), we include government transfers in our estimate of household income. This income provides purchasing power to households, and this purchasing power absolutely informs households’ consumption decisions and savings rates. Excluding these transfers from household income gives an estimate of how market-based income trends by themselves would have affected aggregate demand growth. Including the transfers provides an estimate of how much shifting inequality overall (even including the generally equalizing effect of taxes and transfers) actually slowed aggregate demand growth in recent decades.

The point of Figure E is simply that savings rates vary enormously across the income distribution. The economy-wide savings rate averaged 11.6 percent from 1989 to 2013, while the savings rate for the top 1 percent averaged 47.4 percent. This large difference in savings rates gives rising inequality a very long lever with which to influence trends in aggregate demand growth. A straightforward back-of-the-envelope estimate of how much the redistribution of income toward the top stifled consumption growth involves multiplying each group’s share of income in earlier years by its savings rate and sum across groups, repeating this procedure for later years, and then simply subtracting the later aggregates from the earlier aggregates. Table 2 shows the results of this procedure.

Table 2

Redistribution to high-income, high-saving households is slowing demand growth: Estimated effect of upward redistribution on aggregate demand, 1979, 1989, 2007 and 2012

Bottom 80 80th–90th 90th–95th 95th–99th Top 1 Average
Savings rate, 1989-2013 average 0.8% 1.9% 9.8% 29.5% 47.4% 11.6%
1979 income share 55.2% 15.0% 9.7% 11.3% 8.9%
1989 income share 51.4% 15.1% 9.9% 12.1% 12.2%
2007 income share 46.2% 13.7% 9.5% 12.7% 18.7%
2012 income share 47.2% 14.2% 9.8% 12.7% 17.3%
1989–2007 change in income share -5.2% -1.4% -0.4% 0.6% 6.5%
1979–2007 change in income share -9.0% -1.3% -0.2% 1.4% 9.8%
1989–2012 change in 2007 income share -4.2% -0.9% -0.1% 0.6% 5.1%
1989-2007 demand change -5.2% -1.4% -0.4% 0.4% 3.4% -3.1%
1979-2007 demand change -8.9% -1.3% -0.2% 1.0% 5.2% -4.2%
1989-2012 demand change -4.2% -0.9% -0.1% 0.4% 2.7% -2.0%

Notes: Income shares do not sum to 100 percent because the CBO income data includes households with negative incomes. The shares in the table above are effectively income shares of households with positive income. Negative income is never more than 2 percent of total income, so this failure to round to 100 has only trivial effects on our calculations. The change in aggregate demand is calculated as the change in income multiplied by one minus the savings rate (essentially each income group’s average propensity to consume).

Source: Author’s analysis based on data from the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) and the Financial Accounts of the United States (FAUS) from the Federal Reserve Board and the Congressional Budget Office (2016)

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

The top panel of Table 2 shows the average savings rate for each of the income groups featured in Figure E.11 In the middle panel of the table are estimates of the change in income share of each income group for three overlapping periods: 1979–2007, 1989–2007, and 1979–2012. Between 1989 and 2007, the share of income claimed by the 95th to 99th percentile of households and the top 1 percent of households rose by 0.6 percent and 6.5 percent, respectively. Multiplying each group’s change in income share over this period by their average savings rate implies that aggregate consumption spending fell by 3.1 percentage points from 1989 to 2007 due to the redistribution of income upward, holding all other influences constant. This figure is found in the bottom panel, which shows the demand drag potentially caused by rising inequality for the three periods. While data restrictions keep us from getting average savings rates going back to 1979 (as the SCF does not have reliable data before 1989), there was a large redistribution between 1979 and 1989 as well. The implied demand drag of the 1979–2007 and 1979–2012 periods assumes that average savings rates across income percentiles from 1989 to 2013 characterize these periods as well.

By 2007, the implied inequality-induced drag on aggregate demand that began in 1979 amounted to more than 4 percentage points of GDP every year. Even if we measure from 1989, and we take as given the large (but almost surely temporary) decline in top 1 percent income shares from 2007 to 2012, by 2012 inequality was imposing a drag of over 2 percentage points on aggregate demand growth. It is worth restating that this hit to the level of aggregate demand generated by rising inequality is cumulative: this demand drag is occurring each year by 2007 or 2012. This means that other macroeconomic influences must continuously ratchet up to keep demand growth from flatlining. We of course know one of these macroeconomic demand resuscitators—the sharp fall in the neutral interest rate.

It would take an ARRA every year to compensate for inequality’s drag on the economy

To get a sense of just how large this inequality-induced drag on aggregate demand had become before the Great Recession hit, it’s useful to compare it with well-known policy interventions. Perhaps the best-known policy effort to boost aggregate demand growth in recent decades has been the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA) of 2009. Passed to help stem the downward spiral of the Great Recession and financial crisis, ARRA provided the largest discretionary fiscal stimulus ever provided to the American economy. Its year of peak effectiveness was 2010, when, the Congressional Budget Office (CBO 2015) estimated, it boosted aggregate demand growth (and hence GDP growth) by between 0.7 and 4.1 percentage points of GDP. This upper bound is roughly in line with the estimates above of the demand drag placed on the U.S. economy by rising inequality by 2007. This means that to fully offset the demand drag stemming from inequality using available policy tools, policymakers would need to pass the equivalent of a new ARRA each year. Of course, in the years between 1979 and 2007, other influences boosted demand as inequality sapped it. The most obvious influences were asset market bubbles in the stock and housing markets. But absent transitory (and damaging) influences like large asset market bubbles, the scale of policy intervention needed to keep aggregate demand growth constant in the face of rising inequality is absolutely huge.

Falling NIPA personal savings rate does not invalidate the link between inequality and slow demand growth

The assertion that a large upward redistribution of income over the past generation has slowed growth in aggregate demand implies an increase in economy-wide savings (because more of overall income is going to households that save more). That is why some skeptics could point to the most commonly referenced measure of economy-wide savings—the personal savings rate estimated each month by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) in the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA)—to question our conclusion. Over the past generation, this rate has fallen sharply: from 9.8 percent in 1979 to just 3.0 percent by 2007. (This rate spiked upward during and after the Great Recession, as households responded to huge wealth losses by cutting back on spending to rebuild their net worth.)

This decline in the NIPA savings rate needs to be wrestled with. But both theory and evidence indicate that a falling NIPA personal savings rate can be reconciled with the story of inequality tamping down demand growth. Of all the evidence, the strongest support comes from data that suggest that the NIPA personal savings rate is falling at least in part because it does not include a huge source of savings for the wealthy—unrealized capital gains.

In regards to theory, interest rates are set by the interplay of desired savings and investment in the economy, not actual savings. It is theoretically possible that because the redistribution of income to the top of the income distribution slowed demand growth by increasing the American households’ sector desired savings rate, this slow demand growth constricted overall economic growth and thereby slowed the growth of actual savings (since savings are a function of income growth).12

In regards to data, while a cross-sectional redistribution of income from the bottom 95 percent to the top 5 percent will unambiguously reduce savings all else being equal (holding everything else constant), in the real world it is not likely that everything else holds constant. For example, as income was shifting to the top 1 percent from 1989 to 2012, there were often periods when these households were reducing their own savings rates over time. (As Cynamon and Fazzari 2015 document and the appendix of this paper shows, savings rates of top income households are quite volatile.) If rich households perceived the shift in income toward themselves over this period as permanent, a reduction in savings would have indeed been the textbook economic response. This time-series behavior of rich households with regard to their savings rates does not change the fact that a shift of income growth between income classes has potentially large effects on demand growth. Importantly, even when looking at the lowest savings rate recorded in a single year by top 1 percent households in the Survey of Consumer Finances data between 1989 and 2016, the top 1 percent savings rate is still roughly 10 times higher than the savings rate of the bottom 80 percent.

Finally, and most importantly, it is likely that much of the rise in savings from our decades-long upward redistribution of income has actually materialized as unrealized capital gains, which are not captured by the NIPA personal savings rates. Essentially, there are two ways that households accrue net wealth: they consume less than the full amount of income they earn and save the remainder, or, their stock of accumulated past savings gains in value. This gain in value of the stock of accumulated savings is a capital gain. If households sell the asset then they have “realized” this capital gain. Realized gains are captured in some income sources (such as the CBO income data we used in Table 1). But even if a household does not sell the asset as the asset’s price increases, the household has still seen an increase in wealth due to a rise in unrealized capital gains. The NIPA personal savings rate only measures savings out of current income flows—the difference between income and consumption spending in the U.S. household sector. Figure F shows the change in household net worth as a share of GDP. A broader definition of savings sometimes used by economists, this measure includes not only current income flows that are not consumed, but also the changes to wealth occurring from rising or falling asset prices, i.e., unrealized capital gains. This measure shows no obvious downward trend, although it clearly has become more volatile in recent years.

Figure F

No clear downward trend in household savings if capital gains are included: Three-year average change in household net worth as a share of GDP, 1958—2016

Date Change in household net worth accounted for by capital gains
1958Q1 22.3%
1958Q2 21.7%
1958Q3 21.7%
1958Q4 21.9%
1959Q1 21.9%
1959Q2 21.4%
1959Q3 20.8%
1959Q4 20.6%
1960Q1 20.0%
1960Q2 19.7%
1960Q3 18.7%
1960Q4 18.4%
1961Q1 18.9%
1961Q2 19.2%
1961Q3 20.2%
1961Q4 20.3%
1962Q1 19.7%
1962Q2 17.8%
1962Q3 16.0%
1962Q4 15.4%
1963Q1 15.2%
1963Q2 16.8%
1963Q3 18.4%
1963Q4 19.0%
1964Q1 19.3%
1964Q2 19.1%
1964Q3 18.9%
1964Q4 18.7%
1965Q1 18.4%
1965Q2 18.2%
1965Q3 19.7%
1965Q4 21.6%
1966Q1 22.4%
1966Q2 23.1%
1966Q3 21.3%
1966Q4 19.5%
1967Q1 19.9%
1967Q2 20.5%
1967Q3 21.9%
1967Q4 23.0%
1968Q1 22.8%
1968Q2 23.5%
1968Q3 24.5%
1968Q4 25.9%
1969Q1 26.9%
1969Q2 27.3%
1969Q3 27.0%
1969Q4 26.6%
1970Q1 26.3%
1970Q2 24.4%
1970Q3 23.2%
1970Q4 21.9%
1971Q1 21.6%
1971Q2 23.1%
1971Q3 23.2%
1971Q4 23.5%
1972Q1 23.0%
1972Q2 22.4%
1972Q3 23.2%
1972Q4 24.9%
1973Q1 27.0%
1973Q2 28.8%
1973Q3 31.5%
1973Q4 31.9%
1974Q1 31.5%
1974Q2 29.9%
1974Q3 26.3%
1974Q4 24.1%
1975Q1 23.1%
1975Q2 23.3%
1975Q3 23.7%
1975Q4 23.7%
1976Q1 22.9%
1976Q2 22.5%
1976Q3 22.9%
1976Q4 22.9%
1977Q1 24.0%
1977Q2 25.0%
1977Q3 26.3%
1977Q4 28.8%
1978Q1 30.5%
1978Q2 31.3%
1978Q3 31.2%
1978Q4 31.0%
1979Q1 31.2%
1979Q2 31.7%
1979Q3 32.5%
1979Q4 33.0%
1980Q1 33.2%
1980Q2 34.1%
1980Q3 35.2%
1980Q4 36.4%
1981Q1 37.5%
1981Q2 38.2%
1981Q3 38.0%
1981Q4 37.3%
1982Q1 36.6%
1982Q2 35.0%
1982Q3 33.9%
1982Q4 32.7%
1983Q1 31.7%
1983Q2 31.5%
1983Q3 30.9%
1983Q4 29.4%
1984Q1 27.6%
1984Q2 25.7%
1984Q3 24.4%
1984Q4 24.2%
1985Q1 24.3%
1985Q2 24.8%
1985Q3 25.4%
1985Q4 26.0%
1986Q1 26.7%
1986Q2 27.0%
1986Q3 26.9%
1986Q4 27.2%
1987Q1 28.2%
1987Q2 29.3%
1987Q3 31.0%
1987Q4 31.2%
1988Q1 30.9%
1988Q2 30.4%
1988Q3 29.6%
1988Q4 29.9%
1989Q1 29.8%
1989Q2 29.5%
1989Q3 29.4%
1989Q4 29.3%
1990Q1 28.6%
1990Q2 27.4%
1990Q3 25.4%
1990Q4 23.1%
1991Q1 22.6%
1991Q2 22.1%
1991Q3 22.1%
1991Q4 22.4%
1992Q1 21.2%
1992Q2 20.0%
1992Q3 19.0%
1992Q4 17.7%
1993Q1 16.8%
1993Q2 16.6%
1993Q3 16.7%
1993Q4 17.6%
1994Q1 18.2%
1994Q2 18.0%
1994Q3 18.1%
1994Q4 17.4%
1995Q1 17.0%
1995Q2 17.6%
1995Q3 18.5%
1995Q4 19.8%
1996Q1 21.0%
1996Q2 21.9%
1996Q3 22.1%
1996Q4 22.0%
1997Q1 21.9%
1997Q2 22.9%
1997Q3 24.6%
1997Q4 26.4%
1998Q1 29.6%
1998Q2 31.6%
1998Q3 31.4%
1998Q4 32.6%
1999Q1 32.4%
1999Q2 32.7%
1999Q3 33.6%
1999Q4 35.3%
2000Q1 37.9%
2000Q2 39.3%
2000Q3 40.6%
2000Q4 38.1%
2001Q1 34.0%
2001Q2 30.0%
2001Q3 25.2%
2001Q4 24.0%
2002Q1 22.3%
2002Q2 20.0%
2002Q3 17.2%
2002Q4 13.6%
2003Q1 9.3%
2003Q2 6.4%
2003Q3 6.4%
2003Q4 6.5%
2004Q1 10.9%
2004Q2 16.5%
2004Q3 20.6%
2004Q4 26.3%
2005Q1 29.4%
2005Q2 31.6%
2005Q3 35.8%
2005Q4 39.4%
2006Q1 44.0%
2006Q2 47.9%
2006Q3 49.1%
2006Q4 48.5%
2007Q1 46.4%
2007Q2 43.3%
2007Q3 40.4%
2007Q4 36.2%
2008Q1 30.1%
2008Q2 23.8%
2008Q3 16.4%
2008Q4 6.8%
2009Q1 -1.6%
2009Q2 -9.5%
2009Q3 -14.5%
2009Q4 -16.0%
2010Q1 -16.2%
2010Q2 -16.7%
2010Q3 -17.4%
2010Q4 -17.1%
2011Q1 -15.0%
2011Q2 -10.5%
2011Q3 -6.8%
2011Q4 -2.5%
2012Q1 4.1%
2012Q2 9.9%
2012Q3 16.6%
2012Q4 21.0%
2013Q1 23.0%
2013Q2 24.5%
2013Q3 27.2%
2013Q4 30.6%
2014Q1 32.4%
2014Q2 34.0%
2014Q3 33.9%
2014Q4 35.2%
2015Q1 37.0%
2015Q2 37.8%
2015Q3 38.1%
2015Q4 36.4%
2016Q1 34.4%
2016Q2 32.3%
2016Q3 30.9%
2016Q4 29.4%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Shaded areas denote recessions.

Source: Author’s analysis of data from the Financial Accounts of the United States from the Federal Reserve Board (FAUS) and the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) of the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA)

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

As can be inferred from this data showing no downward trend in net worth, even in the face of falling flows of savings out of current income (shown in NIPA data), capital gains have been large (larger than flows of household savings) and growing in recent decades. For example, as can be seen in Figure G, unrealized capital gains on financial assets constituted more than three quarters of the annual rise in household net worth on average between 1979 and 2016. The remaining quarter was contributed by household savings out of current income.

Further, the rise in capital gains is likely driven by a shift in corporate strategy that has redistributed more profits to shareholding households in the form of stock repurchases and less in dividend payments (as shown in Figure H). Dividends and stock repurchases are just two different methods by which corporations can return the benefits of profits to their owners (shareholders). If firms decide to repurchase their own stock, this bids up the firm’s stock price and causes a capital gain. If the firm instead decides to take money that was being used to repurchase stock and use it instead to just pay dividends to shareholders, these dividends would show up in the NIPA measure of personal income and would be captured in the personal savings rate. Capital gains, again, are not measured as personal income and hence the change in corporate strategy to emphasize share repurchases over dividend payments affects measured savings rates.

In short, much savings among high-income households in recent decades has likely shown up more on corporate balance sheets than on household balance sheets. Further, the specific corporate actions—most notably the use of profits to repurchase stocks rather than pay dividends—has kept most measures of national savings from registering the pronounced increase in wealth deriving from the upward distribution of income. This helps explain why some measures of household savings show strong declines in recent decades even as total income claimed by high-income, high-savings households has increased dramatically: the extra savings resulting from that upward redistribution may be showing up in places besides household balance sheets.

Figure G

Capital gains are a principal source of wealth gains: Share of year-to-year growth in household net worth that is accounted by for capital gains, 1959–2016

Date Change in household net worth
1959Q1 69.0%
1959Q2 69.8%
1959Q3 66.5%
1959Q4 66.6%
1960Q1 58.6%
1960Q2 59.2%
1960Q3 72.4%
1960Q4 73.2%
1961Q1 75.1%
1961Q2 74.5%
1961Q3 76.4%
1961Q4 79.0%
1962Q1 75.5%
1962Q2 83.3%
1962Q3 82.8%
1962Q4 63.6%
1963Q1 66.1%
1963Q2 66.9%
1963Q3 66.1%
1963Q4 82.4%
1964Q1 82.5%
1964Q2 84.4%
1964Q3 83.5%
1964Q4 86.5%
1965Q1 85.5%
1965Q2 113.6%
1965Q3 114.2%
1965Q4 100.5%
1966Q1 79.0%
1966Q2 77.4%
1966Q3 84.1%
1966Q4 84.7%
1967Q1 84.5%
1967Q2 87.5%
1967Q3 85.4%
1967Q4 86.0%
1968Q1 76.8%
1968Q2 77.6%
1968Q3 76.9%
1968Q4 78.1%
1969Q1 54.4%
1969Q2 42.0%
1969Q3 36.4%
1969Q4 30.7%
1970Q1 24.5%
1970Q2 28.4%
1970Q3 9.7%
1970Q4 10.0%
1971Q1 10.0%
1971Q2 30.1%
1971Q3 29.5%
1971Q4 23.7%
1972Q1 23.5%
1972Q2 22.3%
1972Q3 22.8%
1972Q4 23.6%
1973Q1 17.6%
1973Q2 23.3%
1973Q3 22.8%
1973Q4 33.3%
1974Q1 26.0%
1974Q2 41.8%
1974Q3 59.6%
1974Q4 65.1%
1975Q1 72.1%
1975Q2 79.3%
1975Q3 88.7%
1975Q4 88.7%
1976Q1 88.6%
1976Q2 88.6%
1976Q3 89.0%
1976Q4 90.6%
1977Q1 89.1%
1977Q2 89.6%
1977Q3 90.0%
1977Q4 90.0%
1978Q1 88.7%
1978Q2 95.0%
1978Q3 98.1%
1978Q4 97.6%
1979Q1 88.5%
1979Q2 95.6%
1979Q3 87.5%
1979Q4 82.8%
1980Q1 82.6%
1980Q2 82.7%
1980Q3 82.7%
1980Q4 70.4%
1981Q1 69.8%
1981Q2 69.9%
1981Q3 64.9%
1981Q4 64.9%
1982Q1 62.4%
1982Q2 61.9%
1982Q3 60.2%
1982Q4 61.0%
1983Q1 61.1%
1983Q2 61.3%
1983Q3 58.2%
1983Q4 55.1%
1984Q1 54.4%
1984Q2 52.3%
1984Q3 51.5%
1984Q4 50.2%
1985Q1 49.9%
1985Q2 50.4%
1985Q3 49.2%
1985Q4 49.4%
1986Q1 49.1%
1986Q2 49.7%
1986Q3 46.3%
1986Q4 51.1%
1987Q1 52.1%
1987Q2 54.8%
1987Q3 56.3%
1987Q4 62.4%
1988Q1 62.1%
1988Q2 62.9%
1988Q3 62.6%
1988Q4 64.9%
1989Q1 67.8%
1989Q2 69.3%
1989Q3 71.5%
1989Q4 71.1%
1990Q1 66.5%
1990Q2 66.1%
1990Q3 70.2%
1990Q4 70.5%
1991Q1 69.8%
1991Q2 56.2%
1991Q3 55.8%
1991Q4 59.1%
1992Q1 54.5%
1992Q2 44.5%
1992Q3 43.5%
1992Q4 44.1%
1993Q1 38.6%
1993Q2 38.0%
1993Q3 37.5%
1993Q4 38.3%
1994Q1 30.5%
1994Q2 28.7%
1994Q3 28.2%
1994Q4 26.5%
1995Q1 27.0%
1995Q2 33.1%
1995Q3 34.4%
1995Q4 30.3%
1996Q1 30.3%
1996Q2 30.7%
1996Q3 44.6%
1996Q4 44.4%
1997Q1 44.2%
1997Q2 50.0%
1997Q3 60.3%
1997Q4 61.1%
1998Q1 61.7%
1998Q2 62.4%
1998Q3 65.5%
1998Q4 66.7%
1999Q1 66.5%
1999Q2 75.9%
1999Q3 80.6%
1999Q4 81.6%
2000Q1 83.9%
2000Q2 84.7%
2000Q3 85.8%
2000Q4 88.0%
2001Q1 90.2%
2001Q2 91.9%
2001Q3 93.3%
2001Q4 94.1%
2002Q1 94.8%
2002Q2 96.2%
2002Q3 96.5%
2002Q4 96.2%
2003Q1 96.1%
2003Q2 96.3%
2003Q3 97.3%
2003Q4 95.7%
2004Q1 94.8%
2004Q2 96.1%
2004Q3 95.3%
2004Q4 93.2%
2005Q1 92.8%
2005Q2 92.8%
2005Q3 93.2%
2005Q4 92.3%
2006Q1 90.3%
2006Q2 88.9%
2006Q3 89.6%
2006Q4 88.8%
2007Q1 87.9%
2007Q2 92.2%
2007Q3 108.4%
2007Q4 109.9%
2008Q1 111.6%
2008Q2 114.2%
2008Q3 115.5%
2008Q4 116.3%
2009Q1 118.0%
2009Q2 119.2%
2009Q3 119.2%
2009Q4 118.4%
2010Q1 117.1%
2010Q2 118.6%
2010Q3 118.5%
2010Q4 117.8%
2011Q1 117.3%
2011Q2 114.3%
2011Q3 116.0%
2011Q4 114.4%
2012Q1 114.5%
2012Q2 109.7%
2012Q3 106.5%
2012Q4 88.7%
2013Q1 86.5%
2013Q2 84.9%
2013Q3 83.8%
2013Q4 82.1%
2014Q1 80.5%
2014Q2 79.1%
2014Q3 74.7%
2014Q4 73.2%
2015Q1 73.4%
2015Q2 76.0%
2015Q3 76.3%
2015Q4 75.5%
2016Q1 73.4%
2016Q2 74.1%
2016Q3 77.4%
2016Q4 75.1%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Shaded areas denote recessions.

Source: Author’s analysis of data from the Financial Accounts of the United States (FAUS) from the Federal Reserve Board.

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Figure H

Stock repurchases are a growing share of corporate payout to households: Stock share repurchases and dividend payments as share of corporate profits, 1959–2016

Date Share repurchases Dividend payments
1959Q1 -5.0% 21.8%
1959Q2 -4.8% 21.6%
1959Q3 -4.7% 21.6%
1959Q4 -4.8% 21.7%
1960Q1 -4.9% 21.8%
1960Q2 -4.8% 22.1%
1960Q3 -4.9% 22.4%
1960Q4 -4.9% 22.7%
1961Q1 -4.9% 23.2%
1961Q2 -5.3% 23.4%
1961Q3 -5.3% 23.6%
1961Q4 -5.0% 23.7%
1962Q1 -4.7% 23.9%
1962Q2 -4.4% 24.2%
1962Q3 -4.0% 24.3%
1962Q4 -3.9% 24.4%
1963Q1 -3.7% 24.5%
1963Q2 -3.6% 24.2%
1963Q3 -3.1% 24.0%
1963Q4 -2.7% 23.9%
1964Q1 -2.7% 24.0%
1964Q2 -2.8% 24.2%
1964Q3 -2.6% 24.4%
1964Q4 -2.3% 24.5%
1965Q1 -2.0% 24.5%
1965Q2 -2.0% 24.5%
1965Q3 -1.8% 24.5%
1965Q4 -1.5% 24.4%
1966Q1 -1.4% 24.2%
1966Q2 -1.4% 24.0%
1966Q3 -0.9% 23.8%
1966Q4 -0.7% 23.7%
1967Q1 -0.8% 23.7%
1967Q2 -0.9% 23.8%
1967Q3 -1.0% 23.7%
1967Q4 -1.2% 23.6%
1968Q1 -1.3% 23.6%
1968Q2 -1.4% 23.5%
1968Q3 -1.3% 23.5%
1968Q4 -1.1% 23.6%
1969Q1 -1.4% 23.6%
1969Q2 -1.3% 23.7%
1969Q3 -1.3% 23.7%
1969Q4 -1.6% 23.8%
1970Q1 -2.2% 24.0%
1970Q2 -2.5% 24.2%
1970Q3 -2.8% 24.5%
1970Q4 -3.4% 24.8%
1971Q1 -4.0% 24.9%
1971Q2 -4.9% 25.0%
1971Q3 -5.5% 25.1%
1971Q4 -6.0% 25.1%
1972Q1 -6.7% 25.3%
1972Q2 -7.4% 25.2%
1972Q3 -7.8% 25.1%
1972Q4 -8.2% 24.9%
1973Q1 -8.2% 24.7%
1973Q2 -8.5% 24.5%
1973Q3 -8.6% 24.3%
1973Q4 -9.2% 24.0%
1974Q1 -9.6% 23.7%
1974Q2 -9.7% 23.5%
1974Q3 -9.6% 23.1%
1974Q4 -9.5% 22.7%
1975Q1 -9.5% 22.6%
1975Q2 -9.7% 22.4%
1975Q3 -9.5% 21.9%
1975Q4 -9.6% 21.4%
1976Q1 -9.4% 20.7%
1976Q2 -9.3% 20.3%
1976Q3 -8.6% 20.0%
1976Q4 -7.9% 19.7%
1977Q1 -7.3% 19.5%
1977Q2 -6.8% 19.2%
1977Q3 -6.1% 18.8%
1977Q4 -5.7% 18.6%
1978Q1 -5.0% 18.6%
1978Q2 -4.8% 18.5%
1978Q3 -4.4% 18.4%
1978Q4 -4.2% 18.3%
1979Q1 -3.7% 18.2%
1979Q2 -3.1% 18.2%
1979Q3 -2.8% 18.1%
1979Q4 -2.7% 18.1%
1980Q1 -2.6% 18.1%
1980Q2 -2.3% 18.2%
1980Q3 -2.0% 18.1%
1980Q4 -2.2% 18.2%
1981Q1 -1.9% 18.4%
1981Q2 -1.4% 18.8%
1981Q3 -0.3% 19.1%
1981Q4 0.5% 19.5%
1982Q1 0.9% 20.1%
1982Q2 0.8% 20.5%
1982Q3 1.1% 21.1%
1982Q4 0.6% 22.1%
1983Q1 0.0% 23.1%
1983Q2 -1.1% 23.7%
1983Q3 -1.2% 24.4%
1983Q4 -1.5% 25.1%
1984Q1 -0.1% 25.6%
1984Q2 1.8% 26.1%
1984Q3 3.1% 26.8%
1984Q4 4.7% 27.5%
1985Q1 6.6% 28.3%
1985Q2 8.4% 29.3%
1985Q3 10.2% 29.6%
1985Q4 12.8% 30.3%
1986Q1 15.1% 31.3%
1986Q2 17.7% 32.5%
1986Q3 20.0% 33.4%
1986Q4 22.2% 34.1%
1987Q1 22.6% 34.7%
1987Q2 24.1% 34.7%
1987Q3 25.6% 34.9%
1987Q4 27.6% 35.2%
1988Q1 30.2% 34.8%
1988Q2 33.4% 34.3%
1988Q3 35.8% 34.4%
1988Q4 39.3% 34.4%
1989Q1 42.6% 34.8%
1989Q2 43.2% 35.5%
1989Q3 44.1% 36.4%
1989Q4 44.2% 37.1%
1990Q1 44.0% 38.1%
1990Q2 42.9% 38.8%
1990Q3 42.7% 39.3%
1990Q4 42.2% 40.1%
1991Q1 39.9% 40.9%
1991Q2 37.9% 41.5%
1991Q3 35.0% 41.8%
1991Q4 31.6% 42.4%
1992Q1 27.9% 43.0%
1992Q2 26.2% 43.6%
1992Q3 24.3% 44.6%
1992Q4 22.7% 45.5%
1993Q1 20.3% 46.4%
1993Q2 18.0% 47.3%
1993Q3 14.9% 48.2%
1993Q4 13.1% 48.6%
1994Q1 10.0% 49.2%
1994Q2 7.0% 49.3%
1994Q3 5.7% 49.2%
1994Q4 3.9% 48.7%
1995Q1 2.7% 48.3%
1995Q2 1.9% 47.7%
1995Q3 1.7% 47.2%
1995Q4 0.9% 47.0%
1996Q1 0.3% 46.4%
1996Q2 0.0% 45.8%
1996Q3 1.4% 45.1%
1996Q4 2.0% 44.6%
1997Q1 3.5% 43.9%
1997Q2 5.0% 43.4%
1997Q3 6.4% 42.8%
1997Q4 7.6% 42.3%
1998Q1 8.7% 42.2%
1998Q2 9.5% 42.0%
1998Q3 12.3% 42.1%
1998Q4 17.3% 42.2%
1999Q1 17.9% 42.2%
1999Q2 20.7% 42.4%
1999Q3 21.7% 42.5%
1999Q4 21.1% 43.0%
2000Q1 18.7% 43.6%
2000Q2 20.3% 44.3%
2000Q3 20.2% 45.3%
2000Q4 23.4% 46.3%
2001Q1 23.0% 47.4%
2001Q2 23.1% 48.4%
2001Q3 24.9% 50.3%
2001Q4 23.9% 53.9%
2002Q1 23.6% 56.3%
2002Q2 22.8% 58.1%
2002Q3 23.6% 59.1%
2002Q4 22.9% 60.1%
2003Q1 22.6% 60.5%
2003Q2 21.9% 61.5%
2003Q3 21.3% 61.9%
2003Q4 19.0% 62.3%
2004Q1 14.6% 62.4%
2004Q2 15.0% 62.4%
2004Q3 13.1% 62.4%
2004Q4 12.8% 63.3%
2005Q1 13.7% 62.6%
2005Q2 16.0% 61.5%
2005Q3 15.9% 59.4%
2005Q4 17.0% 56.6%
2006Q1 15.0% 55.4%
2006Q2 16.8% 54.1%
2006Q3 17.7% 53.1%
2006Q4 18.4% 51.7%
2007Q1 20.3% 48.1%
2007Q2 23.0% 45.7%
2007Q3 26.7% 44.3%
2007Q4 29.6% 43.5%
2008Q1 31.5% 43.0%
2008Q2 31.8% 43.0%
2008Q3 33.1% 41.9%
2008Q4 36.0% 42.7%
2009Q1 36.9% 43.3%
2009Q2 35.9% 43.4%
2009Q3 34.8% 42.9%
2009Q4 35.2% 42.4%
2010Q1 35.3% 41.0%
2010Q2 35.2% 41.0%
2010Q3 35.4% 41.5%
2010Q4 34.9% 42.9%
2011Q1 34.8% 44.9%
2011Q2 35.0% 45.2%
2011Q3 35.9% 45.6%
2011Q4 36.2% 46.0%
2012Q1 34.8% 45.3%
2012Q2 34.5% 45.1%
2012Q3 33.1% 45.0%
2012Q4 31.2% 45.2%
2013Q1 27.5% 44.9%
2013Q2 27.0% 44.4%
2013Q3 27.3% 44.2%
2013Q4 27.6% 43.7%
2014Q1 26.4% 42.3%
2014Q2 26.4% 41.2%
2014Q3 28.8% 40.5%
2014Q4 30.4% 40.8%
2015Q1 31.2% 41.5%
2015Q2 32.0% 42.1%
2015Q3 33.4% 42.9%
2015Q4 34.1% 44.0%
2016Q1 35.0% 44.6%
2016Q2 36.0% 45.2%
2016Q3 36.4% 45.8%
2016Q4 34.9% 46.3%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Shaded areas denote recessions.

Source: Author’s analysis of data from the Financial Accounts of the United States (FAUS) from the Federal Reserve Board.

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Conclusion

Recent work has highlighted the possibility that rising inequality constitutes an exogenous shock to aggregate demand growth in the American economy. For years, this negative shock could largely be ameliorated by declining interest rates set by the Federal Reserve. But since 2000, the American economy has often found itself with a shortfall of aggregate demand even with short-term interest rates essentially at zero. This means that further increases in inequality will be damaging indeed to prospects of economic growth over the short and medium term unless some other lever of policy fills in the demand shortfall caused by the upward redistribution of income to high-saving households. Further, there is growing evidence that prolonged periods of too-low aggregate demand can damage the economy’s productive capacity.

Policymakers need to get much more serious about avoiding this vicious spiral of chronic demand shortages caused in part by rising inequality degrading productive capacity. Getting serious would mean adopting a more expansionary monetary and fiscal policy portfolio (public investments and expansions to social insurance programs) than has been pursued in recent decades. But, as Taylor et al. (2015) highlight, the scale of upward redistribution of income in recent years would require historically unprecedented changes in taxes and transfers to reverse. They also note that to move the dial on aggregate demand, policy efforts to spur wage increases will have to be much more ambitious than the adjustments to the federal minimum wage in recent decades. We need to enact a much larger raise in the minimum wage and advance policies to boost wage growth for workers making substantially more than the minimum wage.

This makes the EPI’s Raising America’s Pay agenda so vital. It proposes a series of policies that, together, could raise wages for American workers. Pay increases for the bottom 80 percent of households would not just raise the welfare and living standards of these families. Pay increases would also substantially loosen a binding constraint on economic growth: the chronic shortfall in aggregate demand. In short, boosting pay for America’s workers will indeed not only be good for their living standards, it would create a healthier economy overall.

About the author

Josh Bivens joined the Economic Policy Institute in 2002 and is currently the director of research. His primary areas of research include macroeconomics, social insurance, and globalization. He has authored or co-authored three books (including The State of Working America, 12th Edition) while working at EPI, edited another, and has written numerous research papers, including for academic journals. He often appears in media outlets to offer economic commentary and has testified several times before the U.S. Congress. He earned his Ph.D. from The New School for Social Research.

Appendix

The construction of savings rates by income percentile draws heavily on methods pioneered by Maki and Palumbo (2001). Measuring savings rates at the top of the income distribution with the most-used data on consumption, income, and savings—the Consumer Expenditures Survey (CEX)—is difficult because incomes are “top-coded” to preserve confidentiality. This means that reporting on incomes above a certain threshold is suppressed, and instead a single value—the “top-code”—is given to all incomes above the threshold. Further, much recent evidence suggests that the CEX misses a large amount of consumption spending by the rich (see Aguiar and Bils 2015).

Maki and Palumbo (2001) turn to the Survey of Consumer Finances to obtain better measures of savings behavior among high-income households. Besides oversampling wealthy households, the SCF also provides fine-grained income percentile rankings, allowing researchers to identify the top 1 percent of households by income. The measure of saving used by Maki and Palumbo (2001) and this paper is the net acquisition of assets. This is calculated by using the SCF to obtain the share of a particular asset that is held by a given income class. Forty percent of equities, for example, were held by the top 1 percent of income owners in 2013, while 8 percent of residential real estate was held by this top 1 percent. From this acquisition of assets, we subtract the acquisition of household debt using the same methodology.

Then, the SCF shares are applied to data from the Financial Accounts of the United States on the economy-wide net acquisition of those assets by the household sector. So, in 2013, roughly $650 billion in corporate equities was acquired by the U.S. household sector. Assuming that the acquisition was proportional to the cross-sectional share held by each income group, we can measure asset acquisition by income percentile. Finally, we can divide these measures of total asset acquisition (or, savings) by data on incomes from the Congressional Budget Office dataset on effective tax rates and household incomes by percentile. Using the CBO data is one innovation of this paper, as it provides a more comprehensive measure of household income by percentile than what has been used by Maki and Palumbo (2001).

Figure E in the paper reports the average savings rates by income group between 1989 and 2013. While the relative ranking of savings is apparent in each year of the data, there is substantial volatility between individual years in both average savings as well as savings by income group. Much of this volatility seems clearly linked to large movements in asset prices—the bubbles in the stock market and residential real estate markets that characterized the late 1990s and early 2000s, respectively.

Figure A1 shows the estimates for each year of savings by income group. What is apparent is the large swings in savings behavior of the top 1 percent. Between 1989 and 2001, their savings rates declined substantially. From 2001 to 2004, their savings rate increased markedly. However, what is also apparent is that the rich always save orders of magnitude more than the bottom 80 percent.

Figure A1

Household savings rates by income percentile, 1989–2013

Year Average Bottom 80 80-90th 90th-95th 95th-99th Top 1 percent
1989 12.8% 3.4% 1.7% 8.0% 39.0% 47.5%
1992 15.3% 5.2% 9.4% 20.3% 32.5% 50.7%
1995 12.1% 3.5% 6.8% 16.5% 23.0% 48.1%
1998 12.6% 0.5% 4.5% 3.1% 43.0% 48.7%
2001 7.2% 0.6% -5.1% 4.1% 21.4% 37.7%
2004 11.6% -3.6% -6.9% -2.8% 28.5% 86.9%
2007 9.1% -8.0% -7.2% 20.4% 35.1% 45.1%
2010 11.0% 5.8% 8.7% 9.1% 24.5% 23.8%
2013 12.3% 6.6% 4.7% 9.8% 18.7% 38.3%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Note: Shaded areas denote recessions.

Source: Author’s analysis of data from the Federal Reserve Board's Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF), the Federal Reserve Board's Financial Accounts of the United States (FAUS), and Congressional Budget Office data on household income and effective tax rates (CBO 2016)

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Endnotes

1. The estimate is 4 percentage points when measuring how much the drag on demand that began in 1979 was slowing growth by 2007, 3.1 percentage points when measuring how much the drag on demand that began in 1989 was slowing growth by 2007, and 2 percentage points when measuring how much the drag on demand that began in 1979 was slowing growth by 2012.

2. In 2016 dollars, the federal minimum wage peaked in 1968 at just under $10, or about 25 percent higher than today’s federal minimum wage of $7.25. A recent proposal would raise the federal minimum to $15 by 2024, which would be roughly equivalent to $12.50 in 2016 dollars, or about 25 percent higher than the 1968 peak (Cooper 2017).

3. See Bivens (2016) for the measure of the “inequality tax.” The 20 percent refers to the peak level of this tax in 2007, and the collapse in top 1 percent incomes following the Great Recession reduced this inequality tax for a number of years. Given that most measures of inequality have begun marching upward post-2011, it seems a safe bet that the 2007 level of the inequality tax is either with us again today or will be soon.

4. This analysis focuses on the impact of inequality on demand through 2007, instead of 2012 or 2013, because top incomes by 2012 and 2013 still had not recovered from the combination of the stock and housing markets declines associated with the Great Recession. Including only the still-depressed top 1 percent shares of 2012 or 2013 in this analysis would underestimate the effect of rising inequality. The latest year we use is 2012 even though income data from 2013 does exist. We chose not to use the 2013 data because of the pronounced income-shifting for tax reasons that occurred in this year that lowered reported capital incomes. Specifically, asset holders shifted capital income realizations to 2012 to avoid some tax changes that were set to become law in 2013. To get a sense of the extent of this tax-shifting, note that the 2012 top 1 percent share of total income was 17.3 percent, a full 2.3 percentage points higher than the 15.0 percent share held by the top 1 percent in 2013.

5. As noted in Mishel et al. 2012, the rise in capital income’s share is driven overwhelmingly by a higher profit rate, not a rise in capital-output ratios.

6. This presumes, of course, that overall income growth over the period would not have been hurt by not allowing inequality to rise. This is a fair presumption, and Bivens 2016 showed that there is no evidence to support worries that a more equal distribution of income growth in the past generation would have somehow impeded average growth rates.

7. See Bivens (2017) and Ball (2014) for some empirical support for the view that prolonged demand-side weakness eventually bleeds over into serious damage to the economy’s supply side.

8. The difference between potential GDP in 2017 as projected by the CBO in 2008 and potential GDP in 2017 as estimated by the CBO in 2017 is roughly $2 trillion. If the damage inflicted by demand shortfalls that led to the Great Recession and subsequent slow recovery is responsible for a quarter of that gap, it would be $500 billion. (See Bivens 2017 and Yagan 2017 for examples of how demand weakness has bled into slower growth in potential GDP.

9. Holston, Laubach, and Williams (2016) provide a recent example of the analysis and labeling of the “falling R-star” phenomenon.

10. From a household perspective, savings (income minus consumption spending) by definition must show up as the acquisition of an asset, even if that asset is just a larger balance in a checking account.

11. We noted previously in footnote 4 why we do not use 2013 as an end-point in our analysis of incomes. The savings rates from the SCF are constructed using averages from 1989 to 2013. We use the 2013 data in this case because the SCF is only available every 3 years.

12. The dynamic where an increase in desired savings actually induces a demand-shortfall that leads to lower realized savings is well-known to macroeconomists; it has traditionally been called the paradox of thrift. In the decades before the Great Recession, it was largely thought to be a theoretical curiosity, but Eggersston and Krugman (2012) have noted that it is quite possible, particularly when the ZLB binds.

References

Aguiar, Mark, and Mark Bils. 2015. “Has Consumption Inequality Mirrored Income Inequality?” American Economic Review vol. 105, no. 9, 2725–2756.

Alichi, Ali, Kory Kantenga, and Juan Sole. 2016. “Income Polarization in the United States.” International Monetary Fund Working Paper WP/16/121.

Ball, Lawrence. 2014. “Long-Term Damage from the Great Recession in OECD Countries.” National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper no. 20185.

Bivens, Josh. 2016. Progressive Redistribution without Guilt: Using Policy Changes to Shift Economic Power and Make Incomes Grow Fairer and Faster. Economic Policy Institute.

Bivens, Josh. 2017. A “High-Pressure” Economy Can Help Boost Productivity and Provide Even More “Room to Run” for the Recovery. Economic Policy Institute.

Bivens, Josh, Elise Gould, Lawrence Mishel, and Heidi Shierholz. 2014. Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s Our Central Economic Policy Challenge. Economic Policy Institute.

Bivens, Josh, and John Irons. 2008. A Feeble Recovery: The Fundamental Economic Weaknesses of the 2001–07 Expansion. Economic Policy Institute.

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Effective Federal Funds Rate [FEDFUNDS], retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/FEDFUNDS, October, 2017

Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). 2017. “Table 1.1.6. Real Gross Domestic Product, Chained Dollars.” National Income and Product Accounts. Accessed October, 2017.

Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) National Income and Product Accounts. 2017, Table 2.1 Accessed Accessed October 2017.

Congressional Budget Office (CBO). 2008. The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2008 to 2018.

Congressional Budget Office (CBO). 2015. Estimated Impact of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act on Employment and Economic Output in 2014.

Congressional Budget Office (CBO). 2016. The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2013.

Congressional Budget Office (CBO). 2017. The Budget and Economic Outlook: 2017 to 2027.

Cooper, David. 2017. Raising the Minimum Wage to $15 by 2024 Would Lift Wages for 41 Million American Workers.Economic Policy Institute.

Cynamon, Barry, and Steven Fazzari. 2015. “Rising Inequality, Demand, and Growth in the U.S. Economy.” Working Paper.

Eggertsson, Gauti, and Paul Krugman. 2012. “Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo Approach.” Quarterly Journal of Economics vol. 127, no. 3, 1469–1513.

Federal Reserve Board. Various years. Financial Accounts of the United States. Tables B.103, R. 103, F.101, and L.6.

Federal Reserve Board. Various years. Survey of Consumer Finances. Microdata.

Holston, Kathryn, Thomas Laubach, and John Williams. 2016. “Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest: International Trends and Determinants.” Working Paper 2016-11. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

Krugman, Paul. 2013. “Secular Stagnation, Coalmines, Bubbles and Larry Summers.” New York Times, November 16.

Maki, Dean, and Michael Palumbo. 2001. “Disentangling the Wealth Effect: A Cohort Analysis of Household Savings in the 1990s.”

Mishel, Lawrence, Josh Bivens, Elise Gould, and Heidi Shierholz. 2012. The State of Working America, 12th Edition. An Economic Policy Institute book. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell Univ. Press.

Rachel, Lukasz, and Thomas Smith. 2015. “Secular Drivers of the Real Interest Rates.” Bank of England Staff Working Paper no. 571.

Summers, Lawrence. 2016. “The Age of Secular Stagnation.” Foreign Affairs, February.

Taylor, Lance, Armon Rezai, Rishabh Kumar, N.H. Barbosa-Filho, Laura Carvalho. 2015.Wage Increases, Transfers, and the Socially Determined Income Distribution in the USA.” Working Paper, Institute for New Economic Thinking (INET).

Yagan, Danny. 2017. “Employment Hysteresis from the Great Recession.” National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper no. 23844.


See related work on Wages, Incomes, and Wealth | Raising America's Pay

See more work by Josh Bivens