Report | Unions and Labor Standards

Right-to-work is wrong for Missouri: A breadth of national evidence shows why Missouri voters should reject RTW law

Download PDF

Press release

Summary

Currently, 28 states—predominantly in the Midwest, South, and Southwest—have right-to-work (RTW) laws.1 Those states include Missouri, whose state general assembly approved an RTW law last year. In August, voters in Missouri will decide whether to adopt the new RTW law.2

Despite the name, right-to-work laws do not confer any sort of right to a job. Rather, they dilute union bargaining strength by making it harder for unions to sustain themselves financially. Some supporters of RTW laws falsely claim that these laws ensure that no one is forced to be a member of a union or pay to advocate political causes they do not support. But those things are already illegal under federal law. What RTW laws do is make it illegal for a group of unionized workers to negotiate a contract that requires each employee who enjoys the benefit of the contract to pay his or her share of the costs of negotiating and overseeing it. In other words, RTW laws prevent unions from requiring that workers who benefit from union representation pay their fair share of that representation. By making it harder for unions to collect these “fair share fees,” RTW laws aim to restrict union resources and to thereby impede unions’ ability to negotiate better wages, benefits, and working conditions for workers.

Across the country, large sums of money have been devoted to backing RTW bills, with lobbyists claiming that an RTW law in their state would create jobs and boosts wages by attracting companies to the state.3 This report summarizes the evidence showing that these claims are completely without merit. RTW laws do not boost jobs—they restrict unions and hurt wages:

  • Only 5.2 percent of private-sector workers in RTW states are union members or are covered by a union contract, compared with 10.2 percent in non-RTW states.
  • Based on the impact of an RTW law in neighboring Oklahoma, we could expect that nearly 60,000 fewer Missourians working in the private sector would be covered by a union contract if RTW were implemented in Missouri.
  • RTW laws have not succeeded in boosting employment in states that have adopted them. In fact, RTW laws have no causal impact on job growth or unemployment, contrary to the claims of its proponents.
  • RTW laws are associated with lower wages and benefits for both union and nonunion workers. In RTW states, the average worker makes 3.1 percent less in hourly wages than the average worker with similar characteristics in non-RTW states. This pattern of lower wages in RTW states is also true for women workers and workers of color.
  • Through weakening unions, RTW laws hurt the middle class. As union membership has declined in recent decades, the share of overall income received by the middle class is close to a post-WWII low.
  • By restricting the capacity of unions to bargain for workers and thus lowering wages and benefits, RTW laws lower tax revenues and reduce aggregate demand.

Those considering whether to vote for Missouri’s RTW law should consider the consequences—specifically the negative impact on unionization and wages—while giving the proper zero weight to the false claims that RTW laws would boost the state’s economy and attract new businesses.

What is the goal of RTW legislation?

Corporate lobbies advocate for RTW laws not to create jobs or give workers more freedom, but to restrict unionization and make it harder for workers to have an effective voice in negotiating with their employers.4 Under federal law, unions are required to represent every employee covered by a union contract. In RTW states, this in practice means providing expensive benefits to many workers who have not paid their fair share.5 Nonmembers in a collective bargaining unit get all the benefits of collective bargaining agreements, including the higher wages and benefits that unions secure through the bargaining process. And if a non-dues-paying employee has a problem at work, the union is required to represent her—including providing an attorney at no charge if one is needed—in exactly the same way it would represent a dues-paying member. Providing the same range of benefits to dues-paying members and nonmembers who don’t pay fees starves the union and diminishes the ability of unions to negotiate higher wages and benefits for workers.

There are many organizations that, like unions, require membership dues. For instance, an attorney who wants to appear in court must be a dues-paying member of the bar association. Someone may dislike the bar association, but that person must still pay dues if he or she wants to appear in court. Unions in RTW states are the only organizations in the country that are forced to provide all benefits for free to people who opt not to pay for them. This is because unions in RTW states are banned from requiring those who enjoy the benefits of the union to pay their fair share of the costs of providing those benefits.

Right-to-work states have lower unionization levels

Unsurprisingly, states with RTW laws have lower unionization rates, exactly what the corporate lobbies who advocate for RTW intend. Just 5.2 percent of private-sector workers in RTW states are union members or are covered by a union contract, compared with 10.2 percent in non-RTW states—a 5.0-percentage-point difference. It is of course possible that those differences could be being caused in part by other observable differences between RTW and non-RTW states that are related to unionization, such as differences in the industries that make up the states’ economies. But, after controlling for a full complement of observable factors related to unionization—industry, occupation, education, age, gender, race, ethnicity, and foreign-born status—we find that private- sector workers in RTW states are 5.6 percentage points less likely to be union members or to be covered by a union contract.6

It is important to note that while this difference certainly reflects the impact of RTW laws, it may also reflect the effect of unobservable factors that are correlated with both RTW and unionization at the state level, such as other anti-union policies or practices. However, rigorous research on the impact of RTW in neighboring Oklahoma finds that the causal impact of RTW in Oklahoma was a 30.6 percent reduction in private-sector unionization.7 In Missouri, the private-sector union coverage rate in 2017 was 8.2 percent. Based on the findings from Oklahoma, we could expect that if RTW were implemented in Missouri, the private-sector union coverage rate in the state would fall to 5.7 percent over time. This would mean that nearly 60,000 fewer Missourians would benefit from being covered by a union contract compared with what we see today.

RTW laws do not generate jobs

Hundreds of factors affect a state’s economic growth—including warm or cold weather, the urban or rural nature of its economy, whether it possesses natural resources such as oil, and a wide variety of laws. RTW is just one of these factors. Contrary to the claims of RTW proponents, there is no causal pattern of RTW states growing faster or slower—or having better or worse employment indicators—than other states. For instance, in 2017, both the highest labor force participation rate in the country (in North Dakota) and the lowest (in West Virginia) were in states with RTW laws.8

Reviewing claims of faster-than-average employment growth in RTW states, a 2001 report found dramatic employment growth in some RTW states but steep declines in others, with the high-growth states skewing the average.9 Studies that have found positive employment effects of RTW laws have failed to control for a host of factors that would affect employment, from the education level of the workforce to the proximity of transportation hubs to a state’s natural resources or level of manufacturing.10 A 2015 study found “no pronounced effect of RTW laws on state economies.”11

What might be the expected effect on employment if Missouri’s RTW law were implemented? For additional insights, we can turn to a rigorous assessment of the impact of RTW on employment in neighboring Oklahoma. The study found that the passage of an RTW law in Oklahoma had no causal effect on Oklahoma’s overall employment rate or on employment in manufacturing.

Prior to the passage of their RTW law, Oklahoma lawmakers were told that if they passed an RTW law, there would be an eight- to tenfold increase in the number of new companies coming into the state—especially in manufacturing.12 That is the type of claim that is being made in Missouri today. For example, the president of the Missouri Chamber of Commerce, Dan Mehan, has stated that “Missouri’s lack of right-to-work protections has put [the state] at a competitive disadvantage when it comes to attracting jobs,”13 implying that RTW in Missouri would boost job growth. And the president of the Associated Industries of Missouri, Ray McCarty, described “the biggest benefit of right-to-work as its effect on economic development and recruiting companies” to the state.14

But more than 15 years after Oklahoma adopted RTW, none of the promises made by its supporters have come to pass. If Missourians were to approve an RTW law for their state, they could expect similar results.

Unemployment is another key indicator of labor market health. For the past several decades, Missouri’s unemployment rate has largely tracked that of the nation as a whole, rising when national unemployment increased and falling when it declined. But how does Missouri’s unemployment rate compare with its RTW neighbors? As shown in Figure A, Missouri topped out at a higher unemployment peak during the Great Recession than did its RTW neighbors, 9.5 percent in 2010 compared with 7.7 percent. However, Missouri has experienced a stronger recovery and by 2017, Missouri had the same level of unemployment as its neighbors—3.8 percent. Without RTW laws, Missouri was able to bring its unemployment rate down 5.7 percentage points since unemployment peaked in 2010.

Figure A

Missouri’s unemployment rate dropped from 9.5 percent in 2010 to 3.8 percent in 2017, indicating a healthy pace of job growth since the Great Recession: Unemployment rate, Missouri and neighboring RTW states, 2007–2017

Year Missouri RTW neighbors
2007 5.0% 4.4%
2008 6.1% 4.8%
2009 9.4% 7.6%
2010 9.5% 7.7%
2011 8.4% 7.2%
2012 6.9% 6.2%
2013 6.6% 6.3%
2014 6.4% 5.2%
2015 5.0% 4.5%
2016 4.4% 4.3%
2017 3.8% 3.8%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Source: EPI analysis of Current Employment Statistics data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2007–2017

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

If states with right-to-work laws can experience either economic growth or retraction, and if both RTW and non-RTW states can foster booming job markets, then it is clear that something else in these states’ economies, demographics, or policies must be driving job growth, while right-to-work laws account for little if anything in these trends. And in fact, the broader policy agenda often associated with RTW has been shown to be detrimental to state outcomes. When Minnesota and Wisconsin implemented vastly different policies—the former based on strengthening labor standards and other progressive priorities and the latter centered on right-to-work and other measures weakening workers’ rights—the results were clear. Non-RTW Minnesota had stronger job growth, faster wage growth, faster-shrinking gender pay gaps, and greater poverty reduction than its right-to work neighbor.15 The sum of all these metrics leads to a very clear conclusion—outcomes for workers and families have been markedly better in Minnesota, the state that did not follow a right-to work policy agenda.

Time would have eroded any hypothetical benefits of RTW policy

As shown earlier, there is no clear body of evidence that right-to-work laws, in and of themselves, currently have a significant impact on employment growth. But it is worth noting that if they ever did, there is good reason to believe that any such impact would have been eroded by time.

In one part, this is the simple logic of competition. To the extent that right-to-work is a draw for manufacturers, its effect would be greatest on the first state to adopt such a statute. If 49 states protected union security and only one had a right-to-work law, employers to whom this policy mattered would all be drawn to that location. The prospect of becoming the latest right-to-work state in the country is much different. Now any competitive advantage a state might realize would have to be sufficiently powerful enough to draw footloose employers to that state not only over the non-RTW states but also over the other RTW states with identical labor laws.

In addition, to the extent that RTW laws helped draw northern unionized manufacturing firms into lower-wage and less-organized jurisdictions in the South, this dynamic has long since played itself out. Any measure of comparative job growth over the past several decades captures the deindustrialization of the Northeast and upper Midwest and the mass relocation of firms to the South starting in the 1960s, whether in search of cheaper wages, cheaper land, warmer climates, or less regulation. That wave of relocation may show up in the long-term employment growth of Southern states, but at this point the relocation is complete.

There is no such ongoing wave of relocation from which states newly adopting RTW laws might hope to benefit. Thus, one in-depth examination of Southern economic development measured how the effect of RTW laws evolved over time, and concluded that the policy’s impact reached its statistical peak in the 1950s and shrank to statistical insignificance by the 1970s.16 A state newly adopting a right-to-work law today, according to these findings, would receive absolutely no benefit in job growth. Other, recent research has shown that the impact of right-to-work on the probability of male non-employment has lessened over time and by 2010, right-to-work had effectively no impact.17

RTW laws hurt wages

Unionization raises wages for both union members and nonunion workers in unionized sectors.18 Given the union wage boost, it is not surprising that research shows that both union and nonunion workers in RTW states have lower wages and fewer benefits, on average, than comparable workers in other states. Previous research by EPI shows that wages in RTW states are 3.1 percent lower than wages in non-RTW states, after controlling for a full complement of individual demographic and socioeconomic factors as well as state macroeconomic indicators.19 Similarly, the rate of employer-sponsored health insurance and pensions is lower in RTW states.20

How exactly do RTW laws hurt workers who aren’t in unions? When RTW laws weaken unions and lead to lower union wages and benefits, nonunion employers no longer have to compete with higher-wage employers in order to get the best workers, so there is a negative spillover effect in which they lower their own wages and benefits. Conversely, in places where unions are strong, they set standards for entire industries and occupations. As an economic sector becomes more unionized, nonunion employers pay more to retain qualified workers and norms of higher pay and better conditions become standard. To provide a sense of the scope of this effect, a 2016 study looked at what happened to wages when private-sector union density in the United States dropped from 1979 to 2013. Had union density remained at its 1979 level, weekly wages of nonunion men in the private sector would have been 5 percent higher (that’s an additional $2,704 in earnings for year-round workers) in 2013. And wages for nonunion men in the private sector without a college education would have been 8 percent, or $3,016 per year, higher.21 RTW laws, by reducing unionization, hurt the earnings of all workers, not just workers in unions.

Workers—particularly women and people of color—have lower wages in RTW states

EPI research has shown that women and workers of color in non-RTW Missouri have higher wages than their counterparts in neighboring RTW states.22 Figure B shows the median inflation-adjusted hourly wage of workers in Missouri compared with the median hourly wage of workers in neighboring RTW states by race, ethnicity, and gender. Female workers in Missouri typically make $15.28 an hour, while the typical female worker in Missouri’s neighboring RTW states (Arkansas, Iowa, Kansas, Kentucky, Nebraska, Oklahoma, and Tennessee) makes an hourly wage of $14.75, 3.5 percent less than the typical female Missourian.

Figure B

Workers in neighboring right-to-work states make less than Missourians: Median hourly wage, by race/ethnicity and gender, 2017 dollars

Missouri Neighboring right-to-work states
White $17.56 $16.91
Black $14.28 $13.65
Hispanic $13.36 $12.37
Other $17.34 $15.22
Male $19.16 $17.55
Female $15.28 $14.75

 

ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Notes: Calculated using 2010–2017 data. The median wage in neighboring right-to-work states is calculated by averaging median wages in each state. Neighboring right-to-work states are Arkansas, Iowa, Kansas, Kentucky, Nebraska, Oklahoma, and Tennessee.

Source: EPI analysis of Current Population Survey Outgoing Rotation Group microdata from the U.S. Census Bureau

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

The wage disadvantage in neighboring RTW states relative to Missouri exists for all racial and ethnic groups studied. Compared with Missourians of the same race or ethnicity, the median black worker in neighboring RTW states earns 4.4 percent less and the median Hispanic worker earns 7.4 percent less. The impact is even more pronounced for women of color—the median black woman in neighboring RTW states earns 6.2 percent less than her counterpart in Missouri, and the median Hispanic woman earns 12.7 percent less.23

RTW laws hurt the middle class

Unions are a critical part of a system of strong labor standards that makes it possible for regular working people to earn a decent living. Figure C shows that when unions are strong, the middle class is strong, but when union coverage shrinks—as it has in part because of RTW laws and other antiunion policies—a much smaller share of national income goes to the middle class. When the middle class gets a smaller share of income, the households at the top of the income distribution get more, and inequality rises.

Figure C

Union membership rate and share of income going to the middle 60 percent of families, 1917–2016

Union membership rate Share of overall income received by middle 60 percent
1917 11.0%
1918 12.1%
1919 14.3%
1920 17.5%
1921 17.6%
1922 14.0%
1923 11.7%
1924 11.3%
1925 11.0%
1926 10.7%
1927 10.6%
1928 10.4%
1929 10.1%
1930 10.7%
1931 11.2%
1932 11.3%
1933 9.5%
1934 9.8%
1935 10.8%
1936 11.1%
1937 18.6%
1938 23.9%
1939 24.8%
1940 23.5%
1941 25.4%
1942 24.2%
1943 30.1%
1944 32.5%
1945 33.4%
1946 31.9%
1947 31.1% 51.6%
1948 30.5% 52.2%
1949 29.6% 52.3%
1950 30.0% 52.4%
1951 32.4% 52.9%
1952 31.5% 52.7%
1953 33.2% 53.9%
1954 32.7% 53.2%
1955 32.9% 53.3%
1956 33.2% 53.6%
1957 32.0% 54.1%
1958 31.1% 53.9%
1959 31.6% 53.5%
1960 30.7% 53.5%
1961 28.7% 52.8%
1962 29.1% 53.2%
1963 28.5% 53.3%
1964 28.5% 53.2%
1965 28.6% 53.4%
1966 28.7% 53.5%
1967 28.6% 52.8%
1968 28.7% 53.3%
1969 28.3% 53.3%
1970 27.9% 53.1%
1971 27.4% 52.9%
1972 27.5% 52.9%
1973 27.1% 52.9%
1974 26.5% 53.2%
1975 25.7% 53.3%
1976 25.7% 53.3%
1977 25.2% 53.1%
1978 24.7% 53.0%
1979 25.4% 52.8%
1980 23.6% 53.1%
1981 22.3% 53.0%
1982 21.6% 52.5%
1983 21.4% 52.5%
1984 20.5% 52.3%
1985 19.0% 51.8%
1986 18.5% 51.5%
1987 17.9% 51.1%
1988 17.6% 51.0%
1989 17.2% 50.4%
1990 16.7% 50.8%
1991 16.2% 51.0%
1992 16.2% 50.6%
1993 16.2% 48.5%
1994 16.1% 48.6%
1995 15.3% 48.7%
1996 14.9% 48.5%
1997 14.7% 48.2%
1998 14.2% 48.2%
1999 13.9% 48.1%
2000 13.5% 47.5%
2001 13.5% 47.6%
2002 13.3% 47.8%
2003 12.9% 47.9%
2004 12.5% 47.6%
2005 12.5% 47.4%
2006 12.0% 47.1%
2007 12.1% 48.2%
2008 12.4% 47.8%
2009 12.3% 47.5%
2010 11.9% 47.9%
2011 11.8% 47.0%
2012 11.2% 46.9%
2013 11.2% 47.0%
2014 11.1% 47.5%
2015 11.1% 47.6%
2016 10.7% 47.1%
ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Sources: Data on union density follow the composite series found in Historical Statistics of the United States; updated to 2016 from unionstats.com. Data on the middle 60 percent's share of income are from U.S. Census Bureau Historical Income Tables (Table F-2). Because of a redesign in the income questions in 2013, we imputed the income share prior to 2013 using the ratio of the income share using the old and new method in 2013.

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Another way to see how big a force for equality unions are is by looking at how much their decline has contributed to inequality between middle- and high-wage workers. Union decline can explain one-third of the rise in wage inequality among men and one-fifth of the rise in wage inequality among women from 1973 to 2007.24 Should Missouri voters approve the RTW law, to the extent that RTW succeeds in reducing unionization in Missouri, inequality will rise and the middle class will suffer.

RTW policy has a negative fiscal impact and hurts aggregate demand

Economists have long recognized that state and local spending on public services, particularly education and infrastructure, are important components of an economic development strategy.25 These services, however, are put at risk when states adopt a development strategy based on attracting low-wage nonunion employers, which lowers revenues. Union membership has been shown to yield a positive fiscal impact by raising workers’ incomes, reducing the use of public benefits, and increasing the amount of taxes paid. At every level of government—federal, state, and local—union members pay more in taxes than similar nonunion members because they earn more.26 To the extent that right-to-work laws succeed in weakening unions and thus lowering wages and benefits, they also lower tax revenues for local and state government, forcing concomitant cuts in public services.

A right-to-work strategy of economic development that aims to attract lower-wage manufacturers whose location is mobile also threatens growth. That is because the greatest growth opportunities in most state’s economies are increasingly concentrated in construction and service industries that are rooted in local communities and dependent on local demand. If states deploy right-to-work laws that undermine wage standards in manufacturing and other industries, there is a danger that they will inadvertently hamstring job growth by restricting aggregate demand in their local economies.27 Most workers spend a large share of their earnings on rent, food, clothing, and other family needs in local retail and services industries. Thus, a drop in their wages translates into a loss of local economic activity.

If not RTW, what is the right choice for Missouri?

In Missouri and in the United States as a whole, the rising tide of a strong economy once lifted most boats. But today, it’s more likely to lift only the yachts. The broken link between a strong economy and the well-being of most workers threatens the core Missouri value that hard work should pay enough to support a family. To create a more fair, prosperous, and sustainable Missouri, policymakers should be looking to policies that will strengthen—not gut—good jobs. Missouri needs workplace policies that respect and value workers and boost middle-class incomes—growing the consumer spending power that fuels the economy. These policies include increasing the value of the minimum wage, increasing the threshold below which workers cannot be denied overtime pay, providing access to affordable child care, and mandating paid leave and fair scheduling so that workers are able to care for themselves and their families. Missouri should also ensure that workers have a pathway to prosperity by enforcing nondiscrimination laws, providing protections from wage theft and other abuses, and protecting workers who exercise their right to form a union at their workplace.

Finally, Missouri can also help create good jobs and raise wages by investing in education and workforce readiness, and by making investments in Missouri’s infrastructure. By investing in education and workforce readiness, the state can ensure that today’s children will be ready for the future and that current workers can transition into new occupations if they need to. And by investing in infrastructure, expanding transportation, extending broadband access, and investing in water and electric utilities that benefit rural and urban areas alike, Missouri will create good jobs that feed local economies. Finally, Missouri should reform its tax structure so everyone pays their fair share. In these ways—not through right-to-work—Missouri can create an economy that sustains its communities and works for everyone by investing in its people and supporting them in the workplace.

Endnotes

1. Thomson Reuters maintains a web page that lists states with RTW laws. See “Right to Work Laws by State,” Thompson Reuters FindLaw, n.d.

2. “Missouri Proposition A, Right to Work Referendum (2018),” Ballotpedia, accessed June 2018.

3. See Mary Bottari, “Who Is behind the National Right to Work Committee and Its Anti-Union Crusade?” Huffpost, August 5, 2014; and Gordon Lafer, Working Hard to Make Indiana Look Bad: The Tortured, Uphill Case for ‘Right-to-Work,’ Economic Policy Institute, January 2012.

4. See Gordon Lafer, The One Percent Solution: How Corporations Are Remaking America One State at a Time (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell Univ. Press, 2017); and Nancy MacLean, Democracy in Chains: The Deep History of the Radical Right’s Stealth Plan for America (New York: Penguin Random House, 2018).

5. While RTW laws do not prohibit workers from paying fair share fees, they prohibit requiring workers to pay such fees. In practice, this means many workers accept the benefits of union contract coverage but opt to not pay. And when current union members see their colleagues enjoying the benefits of the union for free, they may decide to opt out as well.

6. To determine unionization differences between RTW and non-RTW states, we use ordinary least squares to estimate a union coverage equation using Current Population Survey Outgoing Rotation Group (CPS-ORG) data from 2017, restricting the sample to wage and salary earners ages 18–64 in the private sector. We regress a dummy variable for being covered by a union contract on dummies for being in a right-to-work state, major industry, major occupation, level of education, gender, race, ethnicity, and foreign-born status, along with age and age-squared. The value given is the coefficient on the right-to-work dummy.

7. Ozkan Eren and Serkan Ozbeklik. “What Do Right-to-Work Laws Do? Evidence from a Synthetic Control Method Analysis,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 35, no. 1 (July 2015), https://doi.org/10.1002/pam.21861.

8. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey (BLS-CPS), 2017. Public data series aggregated from basic monthly CPS microdata and accessed through the Labor Force Statistics database and series reports. Accessed June 2018.

9. W. Robert Reed, Does Right to Work Boost Economic Development?Oklahoma Council of Public Affairs, February 2001.

10. The more scholars are able to hold “all other things” equal, the more it becomes clear that RTW laws have little or no positive impact on a state’s job growth. The most recent and most methodologically rigorous studies conclude that the policy has no statistically significant impact whatsoever. See Gordon Lafer and Sylvia Allegretto, Does ‘Right-to-Work’ Create Jobs? Answers from Oklahoma, Economic Policy Institute, February 2011.

11. See Ozkan Eren and Serkan Ozbeklik, “What Do Right-to-Work Laws Do? Evidence from a Synthetic Control Method Analysis” [author-posted version of article published in Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 35, no. 1 (July 2015): 173–194]. After a literature review, the authors conclude, “Some studies find significant effects of RTW laws on various state outcomes, while others find no effect (see for example, Hirsch 1980, Holmes 1998, Farber 2005, Lafer and Allegretto 2011).” The authors did their own study of the implementation of right-to-work in Oklahoma and found no effect on employment. See also Frank Manzo IV and Robert Bruno, The Impact of ‘Right-to-Work’ Laws on Labor Market Outcomes in Three Midwest States: Evidence from Indiana, Michigan, and Wisconsin (2010–2016), School of Labor & Employment Relations at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, April 2017. It is worth noting that the finding of no causal impact of RTW on employment in rigorous studies typically refers to laws passed since 2000.

12. W. Robert Reed, Does Right to Work Boost Economic Development?, Oklahoma Council of Public Affairs, February 2001; and Bill May, “Proponents Foretell Benefits of Right to Work,” Journal Record, September 19, 2001.

13. Celeste Bott, “Right to Work: Here’s What You Need to Know,” St, Louis Dispatch, February 2, 2017.

14. Christopher Brown, “Timing of Missouri Right-to-Work Vote up in the Air,” Bloomberg, May 2, 2018.

15. David Cooper, As Wisconsin’s and Minnesota’s Lawmakers Took Divergent Paths, So Did Their Economies, Economic Policy Institute, May 2018.

16. Robert J. Newman, Growth in the American South (New York: New York Univ. Press, 1984).

17. Benjamin Austin, Edward Glaeser, and Lawrence Summers, “Saving the Heartland: Place-Based Policies in 21st Century America,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, March 2018.

18. Josh Bivens et al., How Today’s Unions Help Working People: Giving Workers the Power to Improve Their Jobs and Unrig the Economy, Economic Policy Institute, August 2017.

19. Elise Gould and Will Kimball, “Right-to-Work” States Still Have Lower Wages, Economic Policy Institute, April 2015.

20. Heidi Shierholz and Elise Gould, The Compensation Penalty of “Right-to-Work” Laws, Economic Policy Institute, February 2011.

21. Jake Rosenfeld, Patrick Denice, and Jennifer Laird, Union Decline Lowers Wages of Nonunion Workers: The Overlooked Reason Why Wages Are Stuck and Inequality Is Growing, Economic Policy Institute, August 2016.

22. Valerie Wilson and Julia Wolfe, Black Workers in Right-to-Work (RTW) States Tend to Have Lower Wages Than in Missouri and Other Non-RTW States, Economic Policy Institute, May 2018.

23. Valerie Wilson and Julia Wolfe, Black Workers in Right-to-Work (RTW) States Tend to Have Lower Wages Than in Missouri and Other Non-RTW States, Economic Policy Institute, May 2018.

24. Bruce Western and Jake Rosenfeld, “Unions, Norms, and the Rise in U.S. Wage Inequality,” American Sociological Review 76 (2011): 513–537.

25. See, for example, Ronald Fisher, “The Effect of State and Local Public Services on Economic Development,” New England Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, March/April 1997; Timothy J. Bartik, Growing State Economies: How Taxes and Public Services Affect Private Sector Performance (Washington, D.C.: Economic Policy Institute, 1996); and Robert G. Lynch, “The Effectiveness of State and Local Tax Cuts and Incentives: A Review of the Literature,” State Tax Notes, September 1996.

26. Aaron Sojourner and José Pacas, “The Relationship between Union Membership and Net Fiscal Impact,” IZA Discussion Paper no. 11310, https://ssrn.com/abstract=3117314.

27. Belman et al. find that higher wage rates have a significant positive impact on a state’s overall economic activity, which the authors suggest reflects increased aggregate demand. See Dale Belman, Richard Block, and Karen Roberts, “Economic Impact of State Differences in Labor Standards in the United States, 1998–2000,” Employment Policy Research Network blog, January 2011.