The Productivity–Pay Gap

Updated October 2022

Most Americans believe that a rising tide should lift all boats—that as the economy expands, everybody should reap the rewards. This outcome can be guaranteed by smart and compassionate policy choices or subverted by policymakers choosing a different path. EPI’s Productivity–Pay Tracker shows the shift toward the latter: Since the late 1970s, our policy choices have led directly to a pronounced divergence between productivity and typical workers’ pay. It doesn’t have to be this way.

The gap between productivity and a typical worker’s compensation has increased dramatically since 1979: Productivity growth and hourly compensation growth, 1948–2022

Year Effective TEP, net Non-supervisory compensation
1948   45.98 48.24
1949 46.94 51.06
1950 50.51 53.04
1951 51.49 53.76
1952 52.65 55.15
1953 54.61 57.84
1954 55.83 59.26
1955 59.33 61.79
1956 60.32 64.20
1957 61.78 65.56
1958 62.99 66.19
1959 65.53 68.06
1960 66.57 69.55
1961 68.76 70.72
1962 71.43 72.75
1963 73.95 74.08
1964 76.38 81.16
1965 79.04 83.25
1966 81.35 84.42
1967 82.48 85.78
1968 85.43 88.13
1969 86.15 89.97
1970 87.78 91.30
1971 91.63 93.81
1972 95.34 98.86
1973 96.94 98.75
1974 94.13 96.57
1975 96.77 96.53
1976 99.15 97.80
1977 100.10 99.68
1978 101.28 101.21
1979 100.00 100.00
1980 97.29 97.33
1981 99.02 96.99
1982 98.13 97.18
1983 101.14 97.62
1984 103.55 96.91
1985 105.24 96.53
1986 107.76 97.15
1987 107.18 95.90
1988 108.62 95.54
1989 109.40 95.57
1990 109.75 94.76
1991 110.46 94.59
1992 114.76 95.21
1993 115.23 95.27
1994 116.26 95.52
1995 116.33 95.06
1996 117.78 95.12
1997 119.57 96.18
1998 122.04 98.47
1999 124.75 99.82
2000 126.18 100.31
2001 127.57 101.74
2002 131.34 103.74
2003 135.56 104.77
2004 139.40 104.35
2005 141.46 103.84
2006 142.03 104.00
2007 143.21 104.79
2008 142.09 104.81
2009 147.56 108.86
2010 151.86 109.78
2011 150.11 108.41
2012 150.19 107.40
2013 151.76 108.41
2014 152.36 108.72
2015 154.90 110.45
2016 155.47 111.38
2017 156.59 111.56
2018 157.95 112.27
2019 159.95 113.83
2020 165.91 117.61
2021 168.77 117.09
2022 164.66 114.83

 

ChartData Download data

The data below can be saved or copied directly into Excel.

Notes: Data are for compensation (wages and benefits) of production/nonsupervisory workers in the private sector and net productivity of the total economy. “Net productivity” is the growth of output of goods and services less depreciation per hour worked.

Source: EPI analysis of unpublished Total Economy Productivity data from Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) Labor Productivity and Costs program, wage data from the BLS Current Employment Statistics, BLS Employment Cost Trends, BLS Consumer Price Index, and Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Product Accounts.

Copy the code below to embed this chart on your website.

Productivity–Pay Tracker

Change 1979–2022:

Productivity

+64.7%

Hourly pay

+14.8%

Productivity has grown 4.4x as much as pay

What is productivity and why did pay and productivity once climb together?

Productivity measures how much total economywide income is generated (i.e., for workers, business owners, landlords, and everybody else together) in an average hour of work. As productivity grows and each hour of work generates more and more income over time, it creates the potential for improving living standards across the board.

In the figure above, pay is defined as the average compensation (wages and benefits) of production and nonsupervisory workers. The pay for this group is one appropriate benchmark for “typical worker pay” because production and nonsupervisory workers have made up roughly 80% of the U.S. workforce over the entire period shown in the figure and because the data for production and nonsupervisory workers exclude extremely highly paid managerial workers like CEOs and other corporate executives. As the figure shows, pay for these workers climbed together with productivity from 1948 until the late 1970s. But that didn’t happen by accident. It happened because specific policies were adopted with the intentional goal of spreading the benefits of growth broadly across income classes. When this intentional policy target was abandoned in the late 1970s and afterward, pay and productivity diverged. Relinking pay and productivity so that workers share in the fruits of their labor will require another pronounced shift in policy.

What broke the link between pay and productivity?

Starting in the late 1970s policymakers began dismantling all the policy bulwarks helping to ensure that typical workers’ wages grew with productivity. Excess unemployment was tolerated to keep any chance of inflation in check. Raises in the federal minimum wage became smaller and rarer. Labor law failed to keep pace with growing employer hostility toward unions. Tax rates on top incomes were lowered. And anti-worker deregulatory pushes—from the deregulation of the trucking and airline industries to the retreat of anti-trust policy to the dismantling of financial regulations and more—succeeded again and again.

In essence, policy choices made to suppress wage growth prevented potential pay growth fueled by rising productivity from translating into actual pay growth for most workers. The result of this policy shift was the sharp divergence between productivity and typical workers’ pay shown in the graph.

From 1979 to 2020, net productivity rose 61.8%, while the hourly pay of typical workers grew far slower—increasing only 17.5% over four decades (after adjusting for inflation).

A closer look at the trend lines reveals another important piece of information. After 1979, productivity grew at a significantly slower pace relative to previous decades. But because pay growth for typical workers decelerated even more markedly, a large wedge between productivity and pay emerged. The growing gap amid slowing productivity growth tells us that the same set of policies that suppressed pay growth for the vast majority of workers over the last 40 years were also associated with a slowdown in overall economic growth. In short, economic growth became both slower and more radically unequal.

If the fruits of economic growth are not going to workers, where are they going?

The growing wedge between productivity and typical workers’ pay is income going everywhere but the paychecks of the bottom 80% of workers. If it didn’t end up in paychecks of typical workers, where did all the income growth implied by the rising productivity line go? Two places, basically. It went into the salaries of highly paid corporate and professional employees. And it went into higher profits (i.e., toward returns to shareholders and other wealth owners). This concentration of wage income at the top (growing wage inequality) and the shift of income from labor overall and toward capital owners (the loss in labor’s share of income) are two of the key drivers of economic inequality overall since the late 1970s.

How can we fix the problem?

For future productivity gains to lead to robust wage growth and widely shared prosperity, we need to institute policies that firmly connect pay and productivity and build worker power. For a description of many promising policies, see EPI’s Policy Agenda—notably the sections on worker power, good jobs, and full employment. Without policy interventions, economic growth will continue to sputter, and the growth we do see will largely fail to lift typical workers’ wages.

Where can I learn more about the productivity–pay gap and how to close it?

A series of EPI reports over the last several years track wage trends and racial wage gaps and their relation to the productivity–pay disconnect. Two foundational papers explain in detail how we measure the productivity–pay gap and why broad-based wage growth is our central economic challenge.

How does EPI construct the productivity–pay graph? 

EPI makes a series of data choices to construct the indices of productivity and pay in the chart above. Our data choices reflect our end goal: to compare growth in the typical worker’s pay with the potential growth in living standards (consumption) that productivity growth represents.  

In brief, we begin with a measure of labor productivity—economywide income divided by total hours worked in the economy. We measure productivity for the broad economy—not just the “nonfarm business sector”—by accessing nonpublic data sources that count outputs from farms, government agencies, and nonprofits. We adjust these calculations for depreciation, and then further for price inflation.   
 
The pay measure starts with the average hourly wage of production and nonsupervisory workers in the private sector, who account for roughly 80% of private-sector workers and thus are a good proxy for the “typical” worker. We adjust this wage for inflation and add inflation-adjusted estimates for nonhealth benefits and health-specific inflation-adjusted estimates for health benefits to arrive at a measure of typical worker pay. 

How does EPI’s productivity–pay graph compare with other versions?

EPI’s productivity–pay graph helps answer a very important question: Do typical workers in the United States share in the benefits of economic growth? The big and growing gap between productivity and pay growth answers that with a resounding “no.” But in order to see this clearly, all of the adjustments we have made to the data are necessary. Failing to understand the role of these data adjustments in highlighting the failure of productivity growth to redound to the benefit of typical workers has led many to focus on inappropriate measures of both productivity and pay, and this has led them to come to wrong conclusions.

How much of the productivity–pay gap is driven by inequality?

Beginning with the August 2021 update, the entire gap in EPI’s productivity–pay figure is associated with rising inequality—inequality among wage earners and the rising share of overall income going to owners of capital rather than to workers for their labor. However, since researchers and analysts may still be interested in factors that account for various parts of the wedge between our measure of pay and other measures of productivity, we decompose these gaps further.